The Republic
of Kazakhstan has a territory of 2 724,900
sq. km, which makes in the ninth largest country in the world, roughly
the same
size as western Europe. Kazakhstan is totally landlocked (11). The
country is one huge plain, sloping from north east to south west. The
plain is
bordered by extensive mountain rangeson
the east and south-eastern borders. Its neighbours are Russia in the north and west, China in the east, and Kyrgyzstan, Turkmenistan and Uzbekistan in the south.Rural
Kazakhstan accounts for over 95 percent of Kazakhstan’s territory, or approximately 260
million hectares (6). Kazakhstan lies between the Siberian Taiga in
the north and the Central
Asia deserts in the
south, the Caspian Sea in the west and the mountain range
of the Tien-Shan and Altay in the east.
Kazakhstan has a continental climate; average temperatures
in the north – 18C in
January, while average temperatures
in the
south are of –3C in January.Summers
are generally dry and the average
temperature in July increases
gradually from 19C in the north to 28-30C in the south. Precipitation
in plain
areas is generally low from 400 mm annually in the north to 100 mm
annually in
the southwest. In the mountainous regions, the precipitation ranges
from
400-1600 mm (5).
As a result of these factors, Kazakhstan has three principal ecosystems:
desert areas, accounting for approximately 55 percent of rural areas;
the
steppe (grassland), accounting for approximately 30 percent; and
mountains and
foothills, accounting for the remaining 15 percent (6). These
ecosystems
provide a varied base for rural economic development encompassing
agriculture,
fishing, hunting, recreation/tourism, extractive industries and the
further
processing of natural raw materials (5).
The Kazakhstan’s climate makes possible to
cultivate wheat, barley, oats and rye in most regions. Irrigated land
in the
southern regions provides the growing temperature sensitive crops such
as
cotton, tobacco, rice, sugar beet, grapes and other fruits. Natural
pastures
accounts for 187, 9 million of hectares of land, which is enough to
feed 70,5
million head of sheep or 7,05 million cattle. Kazakhstan’s climate is favourable for
live-stock farming.It is traditional
occupation of Kazakh people and most pastures have been utilised during
the
year as a forage base (11).
Agriculture
in Kazakhstan is the largest industry in the national
economy occupying an important position in the social-economic politics
of the state.
Approximately 43, 7 percent of the population (total 14,9 million) live
in
rural area and 30,9 percent of the rural population live on less than
the minimum
subsistence income (approximately $ 35 USD per month) (6). At present,
the
total farmland is 222 million hectares and the average population
density is
under 6 people per square kilometre. Approximately 84,5 million
hectares of
agricultural land has been distributed to land users, including 20,5
million
hectares of arable land.
In 2003, Kazakhstan has introduced the private land
ownership by adopting a Land Code. According to this Land Code the
temporary
and permanent land use rights for agricultural land have been
supplemented with
private land ownership. Thus the Land Code outlined the forms of land
tenure
for agricultural lands both land use right and private ownership. The
objective
of this land reform is to establish efficient system in agricultural
sectors,
which will contribute to growth of agricultural production, people
welfare in
rural area and development of the land market.
Economic
transformation of the Kazakhstan economy has brought many changes to
the agricultural production and the rural economy. Employment
opportunities
have been severely affected by disintegration of economic relations
between
former republics of the Soviet
Union and the
concomitant fall in production. Further problems originated
with various constraints on the ability to sell agricultural
commodities on the
internal and external market at appropriate prices. The numbers of
unemployed
people have increased significantly after conducted restructuring and
privatization of state and collective enterprises and the abilities of
the
state to help such people are very limited. Thus agricultural reforms,
including land privatization are considered an important and key issue
in the
overall transformation of the economies of the former socialist world
(15).
During
2002-2003 the President of the Republic of Kazakhstan approved two large scale national programs:
the National State Agrofood Program for 2003-2005 and the National
Rural
Development Program for 2004-2010. In addition, the President announced
in
April 2002 that years of 2003-2005 would be Kazakhstan’s “Years of Rural Revival”. Also,
the Government has paid a great deal of attention for transforming
agricultural
production into a stable factor for economic growth. Three main
priorities have
been designated for development of rural area:
-providing
food security;
-a gradual increasing in
agricultural
production and the growth of sales on either
- the internal market and international market;
-establishment of proper
living conditions in
the countryside (7).
Irrespective
of whether the Government spends sufficient amount of funds on existing
state
support programs, the main tasks of agrarian reforms at this stage are
the completion
ofrural land reform and the
creation
of the necessary legislative base for private landowners to use the
land efficiently. The land use rights together with
uncertainty and instability of recent land legislation did little to
stimulate
or enhance the quality of land and attract long term investments in the
agrarian sector (7).
The
experience of many developed
countries has shown that way of economic
prosperity depends on the effective implementation of agrarian reforms,
particular land reforms. The greatest reform progress has been made by
those countries
that are reforming in very large steps, which are provided by political
will of
authorities. It is relevant for countries of Central and Eastern Europe. On the contrary, CIS countries implement
the agrarian reforms in the way of a gradual approach. There has only
slight
progress in the core countries of the CIS countries and consequently
the
agrarian reforms have not met the original expectation (16). Thus there
are
some needs for further steps in the agrarian reforms in CIS countries,
including Kazakhstan in order to increase the
agricultural production that in turn will develop the rural sector and
contribute to welfare of the rural habitants.
The aim
of this paper is to investigate the economic and social aspects of land
reform
in Kazakhstan. The
following issues are to be considered in this paper: - the
economic transformation of agriculture during last decade and the
introduction peasant
farms since the early1990s, the
privatization of state agricultural enterprises, the distribution of
land
shares to inhabitants of the rural areas; -the
regulatory framework for each stages of
land reforms, the institutional bases that have been established to
strengthen the
legal basis for land relations and to encourage entrepreneurial
initiatives in
agricultural production, desirable state support policies to farms and
peasants
farms to help in achieving sustainability in their farming activities; -potential
impact of land reform on poorhouseholds and considering
way to mitigate the most negative impacts,
an analysis of proposed alternative policy scenarios and
the
identification of appropriate and sound policies in land issues.
1. Land Legislation Development
in Kazakhstan
1.1. Overall Review of Land
Legislation Development.
As in
other countries of the CIS, the land reform in Kazakhstan, is concerned
with
developing a legal and institutional framework, which will allow the
transfer of
real property assets (land and structures built on land) from state
control to
a variety of legal entities(4). This transference of land and property
assets
was made by means of land and property shares as in other CIS
countries.
The
Law
on Land and Land Relations has been replaced several times by
authorised legislative
acts such as the Presidential Decrees and Laws of the Republic of Kazakhstan. The first attempt to reform land
relations was taken by the Supreme Council of the KazakhSovietRepublic with introduction of the Land Code in
November 1990. Despite this Land Code maintaining the dominance of
state
ownership of land, it did ensure various essential changes in land
arrangement
some of the key features by providing citizens with the right to
possession for
life of land plot for a peasant farm, for construction, for subsistence
production, horticulture and cattle breeding, summer cottage
construction and
traditional handicraft.
Before
the Land Code was introduced, the Law “On Peasant Farm in the Kazakh
Soviet
Republic” (21, May 1990) established the peasant farm (private family
farm) as
an independent farming entity, provided peasant farms (private family
farm) an
independent farming entity ensuring that it would enjoy equality with
other
business entities in agriculture. This meant that the organizational
and the
legal form of non-state agricultural farming entity were introduced
into the
practice of the country. The Law set out the principles of
organization, the activity
of peasant farms, declared its business independence and stated that
produced
commodities and received income are the property of peasant farms and
could
used by their own discretion. Life inheritable tenure for a land plot
was
introduced for private family farms, based on labour contribution of
each
member and joint ownership on the productive tools and property.
According to
this Law the land plot under life inheritable tenure is not divisible
and it could
not be subject of a sale, exchange, lease and transference as a gift to
external persons. The land plot might be transferred to member of this
family
peasant farm due to inability of the head of peasant farm to work
because of achievement
of pension age or losing the ability to work. The
land plot should be inherited to successor
in case of deaf of the head of the peasant farm. All those transfers of
land
plots to inheritors were made possible by the introduction of the Civil
Code at
the end of 1994. When the Civil Code took an effect on March 1995,
those who
had been granted lifetime inheritable tenure status were allowed to
sell, gift
or lease their land. The same legislation allowed the transfer of life
inheritable tenure rights to the capital stock of an enterprise (4).
The next Law “On land reform in
the Kazakh
Soviet Republic” (28, June 1991) was intended to create economic and
social
conditions for effective functioning of various business entities,
involved in
farming and to ensure rational land use and to achieve stable increase
in agricultural
commodities production. (8). This law provided for the basic the basic
norms of
land redistribution as regards state enterprises privatization and the
reorganization
of collective farms. The land legislation created a special land fund
for local
representative bodies to grant land for life to those wishing to use
the land for
farming, private ancillary farm, cattle breeding, horticulture, or
construction
were introduced in thisland
legislation. The special land fund was created mainly through the
withdrawal of
“irrationally” used land (9).
The Presidential
Decree “On Some Issues of Land Relation Regulation” (# 1516, 24 January
of
1994) provided that land parcels could be granted to citizens and legal
entities for temporary use for up to 5 years (short-term rent) and up
to 99
years (long term rent). In both cases, the user would need to pay rent.
This decree
also set out the rights of citizens and legal entities for purchasing
land use
rights or renting them in the case of privatization of non –
agricultural real
estate.
The 1994 Presidential Decree “On Further
Improvement of Land Relations” (#1639, 5 April of 1994) allowed that
citizens
and legal entities could sell, rent out or pledge their various lands
rights as
collateral. They were also entitled to sell these abovementioned rights
to statutory
fund of joint stock companies, to partnerships, co-operatives,
including those
that included foreign participation. In this way, land use rights
became the subject
of sales, purchases and other property transaction. This decree could
be seen
as a significant step in adapting land relations to market conditions
and
created legal basis for a land market.
The Presidential
Decree (having the force of law, in this case) “On land“ was adopted
December 22nd
1995 and was the first the first legislative act on land relations,
which complied
with the basic legislative acts such as the Constitution of Republic of
Kazakhstan and the Civil Code, (in effect in March 1995). Thus the new
introduced
institutions of land ownership were legally bound to the abovementioned
basic
legal act.
In
this Law “On land” citizens and legal entities had the right to acquire
a land
parcel for private ownership and land was recognized as real estate and
all transactions
were permitted with these land parcels. At the same time forest land,
and land
relating to water resources fund, land under settlements and especially
protected natural reserves remained under the state ownership. Land
parcels
were granted to citizens for certain purposes, such as conducting own
subsidiary farms, horticulture and summer residence construction. As
concerned
legal entities land parcels were granted to them for technological
needs,
particular for the construction of structures on land and construction
of
living houses.
Farmland
remained under the state ownership. Non-state legal entities and
citizens had
the right to acquire land plots with permanent land use rights while
secondary
land users and foreign entities had the right to possess land plots on
a scheme
of temporary land use rights for between 3 years and up to 99 years.
The
new property institutions such as the right to private ownership on
lands,
permanent land use rights, the right for limited use of other land
parcel
(servitude) and condominium have appeared in the land legislation of
the Republic of Kazakhstan.
The
third stage of land reform legislation in Kazakhstan was characterized by the adoption
of a substantial number of legal acts. After introducing the Law “On
land”
approximately 100 legislative acts were adopted, creating the
legislative infrastructure
for market land relations. This has not been changed significantly by
further
laws and measures. Some acts were introduced to support and reinforce
private
ownership on land, use of land by non-state legal entities, the
creation and
defence of the land market, and for ensuring state control for the
purpose of
safe and rational use of land. All these legislative acts were brought
in to
transform land relations in conjunction with emerging market conditions
(9).
Despite its breadth the Law ”On
land” was limited by the Constitution of Kazakhstan, which provided
that the Presidential
Decrees were valid until the relevant law was adopted by the Parliament
of the
Republic of Kazakhstan. The necessity to issue the Presidential Decrees
at the
end of 1995 was explained by fact, that the Constitutional Court recognized the election of deputies
to the Parliament as illegitimate by its decision and therefore the
Parliament
was dissolved by the President. Then the President had taken the power
to issue
laws in the form of a presidential decree. On 24th January
2001 the Parliament
adopted a new Law “On Land” and this Law replaced the previous Law ”On
Land” of
1995.
After
adopting the Law “On land” of 2001 the institution of land use rights
was
changed significantly. The permanent land use right of citizens and
non-state
legal entities was cancelled and the duration of long term temporary
land use
rights was reduced from 99 years to 49 years. At the beginning of the
land
reforms peasant farms had the right of inheritable land tenure for
life,
subsequently, they were given permanent land use rights and finally
they were
allotted only temporary land use rights. The Law “On Land” of 2001
retained the
possibility of permanent land use right only for state land users. Thus
the
rights of landuser, particular the peasant farms were worsened by this
introduced law.
Some
essential differences in land tenure between state and non-sate
landusers were
established by the new legislation. The latter were allowed to alienate
their land
use rights by their own discretion, to rent out their land use rights,
pledge
the land to another and implement all other deals with respect to their
land
use rights. Thus the non-state landusers with its temporary land use
rights had
a status, very close to private ownership.On
the contrary, state legal entities as permanent
landusers were restricted
in such business deals and only can do it only by the consent of the
authorized
state bodies. This Law enlarged the sphere of responsibility in land
relations.
While
increasing the scope of legal freedom also this Law enlarged the sphere
of
responsibility in land relations. New sanctions were introduced in the
form of
more sophisticated property penalties that took into account the type
of infringement,
the size of damage and the degree of public danger.
In
addition to these measures land zoning was introduced in this law.
Accordingly,
ten zones were determined on the territory of Kazakhstan and these
vary from forestry to steppe zone to central Asian mountain and
southern
Siberian mountain, including deserted and subtropical-deserted zones.
This zone
specialization of land in Kazakhstan has had a
strong influence on the development of land legislation, binding other
interrelated legal norms and documents.
This
land legislation retained certain functions to organize and provide for
rational
land use and land protection. The role of state remained considerable
and its main
functions can be laid out in the following: -determination
of state policy in the area of use and protection of the land fund of
Republic; -establishment of the legal regime of land,
proceeding from the categorisation of land by its designation; -establishing
measures to govern the condition
of sales of land ownership and land tenure for agricultural land; -planning
of land use; -establishment,
change and termination of
land use rights in cases established by legislation; -implementation
of control for right use and protection of
land; -implementation
of land monitoring, land
cadastre and land arrangement. -solving
land disputes; -determining
the liabilities and consequences
for land legislation offences.
In 2003, Kazakhstan introduced private land ownership
by means of adoption of the Land Code. According to this Land Code the
temporary and permanent land use rights, which were established
previously in
land tenure for agricultural land were supplemented with the addition
of private
land ownership. The Land Code of 2003 outlined the forms of land tenure
for
agricultural land and provided for farms and faming entities to enjoy
land
tenure by means of private land ownership or temporary land use right.
The aim
of the introduction of private ownership for agricultural lands was to
further
promote the development of market relations in rural areas and so help
to
create a land market, which will facilitate the transition of
agricultural land
to efficient agricultural producers.
1.2 Ownership of Land.
“The
concept of ownership is fundamental to the realisation of an assets
full
economic potential (4)”. With these
words land ownership is made a cornerstone to agrarian reforms. Given
the
important role that land plays in transition, the very concept of land
ownership
ought to be considered. Under the Civil Code “ownership” is very close
to Roman
Law and combines the ability to: -freely acquire or dispose of an assets,
either by purchase/ sales or gift; -possess an asset in the sense that it
contributes to the enhancement of an entity’s worth; -use an asset to provide benefit, either in
cash or kind (4). “In
1991 the Constitution (Article 46) stated that all land in Kazakhstan was the property of the state and
as a consequence all other forms of “ownership” were at the discretion
of the
state (4)”. The Land Code of 1991 did not intend to embrace the Roman
law
concept of ownership. The land reforms at this time were concerned with
the
transfer of land plots to the various form categories of permanent
ownership,
which was restricted to state enterprises lifetime, inheritable tenure,
temporary and permanent use, and leasing. From
1991 to 1995 the abovementioned categories of land ownership and use
remained
in force. Attempts were made to bring these categories closer to the
Roman law
definition by relaxing the terms and conditions of ownership.
Nevertheless, the
provisions of the 1991 Land Code remained legal vacuum because there
was no
legal basis for fundamental terminology such as “ownership”
(non-state),
“inheritance” and “enterprise” (4).
By
introducing the Civil Code in 1994 made significant change step towards
a Roman
definition of ownership. However, in practice all land transaction such
as
purchase, sale lifetime inheritable tenure agreements remained the
subject to
administrative approval. Similarly, the local administration retained
the right
to determine the value and other terms of any sale (4).The main weaknesses of this approach was that
the actual granting of land to citizens for creating peasant farms was
conducted
at the discretion of the local representative bodies and subject to
their to regulate
and control all transactions.
Articles
24 of the 1991 Land Code contained a long list of reasons why an
individual
could be deprived of previously granted land rights. Many of these
conditions
were couched in broad term that gave local authorities considerable
interpretative freedom. There were cases of individuals having their
land
rights rescinded or changed hereby introducing uncertainty into the
process (4).
The Civil
Code (legally in force March 1995) provided the legal basis for
private
sector entrepreneurial activity such as the right to non-state
ownership, the right
to establish business enterprises and etc. However, with respect to
land the
Civil Code (Article 193) reiterated the exclusive right of the state to
such
ownership. This position was consistent with both previous legislation
and the
Constitution at that time (4).
The
introduction of a new Constitution of Republic of Kazakhstan, adopted
by
national referendum on August 30th 1995 provided that in addition to
state
ownership of land, there was the possibility of agricultural land being
held
under private ownership. The new
Constitution guaranteed the equality and equal defence of state and
private
ownership. These constitutional norms became the ground for the
creation of
new, more market oriented land legislation.
This
constitutional norm enabled a Presidential Decree “On Land” to be
issued in December
1995 on which limited private ownership of land was introduced. Private
ownership was allowed for personal households plot, gardens and dachas.
However, land of agricultural value (except for the households plots
previously
mentioned) may not be granted for private ownership status and this
included
peasant farms. At that time peasant farms fell into the category of
permanent
use and were provided with permanent land use rights.
The
administrative regulation and control of land transaction were weakened
by the adoption
of this Law “On Land”. Henceforth, it was possible for two parts to
legally
agree the purchase or sale of a land plot between themselves at a
mutually
agreed price and to have the transaction notarised without
administrative
interference. This legislation sought to limit administrative abuses
such as changing
or rescinding land rights yet ownership
and use rights could still be rescinded for certain offences, such as
violating
land use assignment categories, using agricultural land for
non-agricultural purposes,
causing ecological damages or as a sanction for a criminal convicted of
a
criminal offence (4).
The
next Law “On land“ in 2001 did not make any substantial changes in the
concept
of ownership. Permanent land use rights were replaced by long term and
short
terms temporary land use rights with state enterprises being granted
the
permanent land use right. Non-state land users held the right to rent
out their
land use rights for periods not exceeding their lease period with
state. Also,
the non-state land users had the same rights to sell, exchange, gift
and pledge
as collateral. These temporary land use rights are very close to
previously
established permanent land use rights although from an economic and
common
sense perspective the switch from permanent to temporary land use is
difficult
to understand.The replacement of
permanent land use rights was made without any clear explanation and no
commentators have been able to find any reason that could explain this
change
in land use rights.
The
land legislation began in 1990 with the introduction of the concept of
lifetime
inherited land tenure. Then Government introduced permanent land use
rights.
This was promising in terms of developing a land market. The introduced
temporary land use rightundermined
the sustainability of land tenure
and it gave less confidence to owners that their land plot would not
taken by
officials some time in the future or that the conditions of land tenure
would
not renewed as they had been granted. Thus the Government changed land
legislation to the direction, which has deteriorated the status of
landusers.
It
is necessary to note that provisions of “On land” of 1995 and ”On Land”
of 2001
did not contain the legal norms for the obligatory replacement of
documents, proving
the land tenure. The 1995 Law “On Land” provided the legal documents,
proving
the right of citizens and legal entities and issued before adoption of
this
edict would be remain in force while the 2001 Law “On Land” provided
that the
process of renewing documents from permanent to temporary status would
be at
the request of the landusers.
Despite
these provisions on the status of pre-existing documents various state
bodies
forced landusers to change their legal documents from the permanent
land use
right and lifetime inheritable possession to the temporary land use
rights both
for legal entities and peasant farms. Thus the Kazakh authorities they
did not respect
the plurality of land ownership, which were promulgated in previous
land laws.
1.3. State Farm
Privatization.
Farm
privatization took place in several phases as in other CIS countries.
Although
the farm privatisation was concerned with transforming state
agricultural
enterprises the privatisation legislation concerned other forms of
agricultural
enterprise as well. It should be noted that the farm privatisation
legislative
framework evolved in a piecemeal approach rather than introducing a
single
comprehensive set of laws with determinate outcome.
Early
farm privatisation phase began in 1990 with adopting the Law on Peasant
Farms
and the entire process was placed in the hands of local
administrations. Land
for creating these peasant farms was either appropriated from state
agricultural enterprise or allocated out of a special land fund
established for
this purpose. The legislation contributed to creation of several
hundreds farms
in the form of individually or family owned farms. As this process was
made
without having all the necessary guidelines and procedure the
implementation of
farm privatization was highly subjective (4). The result was that not
so many
people believed that the lifetime inherited land tenure would remain in
the
business environment, which remained under state control and maintained
the
principle of the command economy. In addition, employment in the state
agricultural enterprises was self-sufficient for many and preferable to
taking
the entrepreneurial risks, associated with private farming.
In 1992 legislation set out how
privatisation of state farms could be more equitable than before.
Privatisation
was to be achieved, primarily through the distribution of assets to
employees
(current, retired and ancillary). All those entitled would receive land
shares
providing an equal amount of land. Similarly the property of state
enterprises
was allocated in the form of asset shares expressed in monetary terms
taking
salary, years of service and professional skills into account. The
owners of
shares could use them to: -form
individual (family) farms; -contribute
to the capital stock ofjoint stock
companies, co-operatives or collective enterprises; -sell
or exchange with other
shareholders. This
process was placed in the hands of the State Property Committee (4).
This
legislation had limited success. One of the reasons why the
privatisation of
state agricultural enterprises did not meet the intended expectation
was that
enterprise legislation, allowing the creation of various types of
business was
not adopted. Only the Civil Code, which came into force in March 1995,
laid
down the basic freedom of entrepreneurial activity and defined the
various
forms of business enterprises including: partnerships, limited
partnerships and
joint –stock company. These forms as well as productive cooperatives
were
described in the Civil Code but during 1992 -1994 farm employees had
very
restricted legal options and were often unaware about all the options
available
to them (4).
By 1994
it was clear that farm privatisation legislation was not succeeding in
creating
significant numbers of viable new farms. The majority of former state
agricultural enterprises merely underwent a change of name. In an
attempt to
speed up the process new legislation was passed (4). The Presidential
Decree
“Concerning the Transference of sovkhozes Property Part to Director
Ownership”
(1585, March of 1994) allowed the transfer of 10 % of the land shares
of an
enterprise to the farm director, who had held the position of director
for
twenty years. A further 10 % could be allocated on a temporary basis
and then
transferred to full ownership after five years of satisfactory
performance. The
Government Resolution (216, February of 1994) also allowed the sale of
selected
agricultural enterprises to individuals through closed tender. Some 34
sovkhozes were selected and about 20 sovkhozes were sold into private
ownership. Each buyer was allocated 20 % of the equity and employees 49
%. The
remaining 31 % was held by the state and allocated to the buyer under
certain
conditions. The buyer was required to assume the debts of the farm.
These two
procedures were temporary measures which were not longer applicable,
because
the conditions of closed tenders were not appropriate to potential
owners of
these state and collective enterprises.
In 1995
the farm legislation framework became more consistent, when various
parts of
legislation were put together. This farm privatisation legislation was
based
upon the same principles of equitable distribution of land and assets
shares,
but with the added benefit that the various forms of business
enterprise, which
could be adopted, had a basis in the civil law. Broadly, the various
forms of
business had definitions similarly to those in market economies.
By the
middle of 1996 and according to official statistics 2332 state
agricultural
enterprises had been privatised and 6050 new farming entities had been
established by new owners on the territory and farmland of these state
enterprises. The conversion rate of approximately 1:2,6. The most
significant
types of non-state farming entities were collective enterprises, small
enterprises and co-operatives. The term of collective enterprise was
used by
local authorities to distinguish a new voluntary association of
shareholders
from the old state agricultural enterprises. In practise, these
associations
usually conveyed a change of the name and modest re-organization and
little
else. The same management and farming activities were pursued.These called collective enterprises and joint
stock companies retained about three quarters of the land and assets of
the
privatised state agricultural enterprises. In other words, three
quarters of
agricultural production assets did not change their economic and social
status.
The conversion of state agricultural enterprises into peasant farms did
not
proceed at the desired level and the number of newly created peasant
farms
amounted to only 1591 units for the same period, which was less than
the actual
number of privatised agricultural enterprises (4). All those newly
established
farming entity obtained the land under permanent land use rights. As
these
collective enterprises have been owned by
The
further stages of farm privatisation were characterised that
restructuring,
mainly of these collective enterprises was left by “market forces” with
the
increasingly active involvement of private businesses. The relevant
market
legislation had been developed by legislation and farm privatisation
and
restructuring took its place in the framework of civil legislation with
additional legislative acts, considering the specific features of
agricultural
production. Where climatic and marketing conditions were favourable
some farms
were successfully restructured by their management and private
businesses.
Considerable proportions of farms though were subject to bankruptcy and
liquidation procedures.
A significant
number of private trading businesses were suppliers of input for
agricultural
production mainly in the form of fuel and seed. They were often
involved in
informal financing of agricultural enterprises or barter trading. The
terms of
seasonal financing and trading barter were largely unfavourable for
agricultural enterprises. Owing to the predatory terms of barter
contract and
short-term financing provided by trading companies the collective
enterprises
were usually heavily indebted.It was
the only option for agricultural producer under trading companies and
furthermore there was no assess to either state or banking financing.The result was that many of these
agricultural collective enterprises failed to meet their contractual
obligations under such contract with the trading companies and the
majority of
these enterprises were acquired by creditors. The shareholders and
workers of
these enterprises could withdraw the land designated in their land
shares
alongside their property shares but they were obliged to take part of
debts of
agricultural enterprises in an amount of corresponding to their share
of
participation. The result was that shareholder and workers had to leave their
land shares in business entities, established by these private
businessmen. In
this way private businesses entered into the agricultural sectors and
assumed a
dominant position in agricultural production.
As result
of these actions shareholding became to concentrate in the hand of
former
senior personnel, administrations or private businessmen. And
additional reason
was that many land shareholders, particularly pensioners and social
workers
used their land share rights for leasing. For this they received rental
payments, mainly in kind, which covers the basic needs in food and
animal
breeding such as feed and hay.
A mutual
economic dependency developed between land share owners and newly
established
private enterprises. Land shareowners require inputs (animal feed, seed
end
etc) acquired from private enterprises to sustain their personal
subsidiary
plot and cattle breeding activities. Also, the decision to transfer
land shares
to large private entities in the form of a lease was based on the
possibility
that the land share owner could be employed by this farm either
permanently or
temporarily for seasonal work. This employment provided rural citizens
with
cash, which was very important because of the absence of other
alternatives in
the rural area. Thus, farm privatization legislation contributed to the
creation of new private agricultural enterprises, which occupied
considerable
farmland for agricultural production mainly through the lease of land
shares
from rural inhabitants.
In 1998
all newly appeared non-state enterprises of different categories were
required
to be re-registered in order to be comply with the Civil Code.By the end of 1998 in percentage, 69, 3 % of
the agricultural and arable land belonged to large-scale enterprises
such as
limited partnerships, agricultural co-operatives and joint stock
companies (2).
These large-scale enterprises are the backbone of agricultural
production at
present. In many cases, the ownership or majority of shares of this
type of
enterprises are in the hand of one person or certain business groups.
Thus farm
privatization ended with up with emerging private businesses, which had
sufficient funds and funding from commercial banks and access to local
and
republican authorities. At the same time huge number (95 460 as of
1.01.2002) of peasant farms appeared in the agricultural sectors. This
amount However,
the amount of agricultural land under the land tenure of peasant farms
is
considerably less than that held in private business entities.
1.4 Land Sharing
The land
sharing mechanism was designed to be a tool for the equitable
distribution of
land and assets of former state agricultural enterprises in the
framework of the
state properties privatization program among rural inhabitants and
former
workers of these enterprises. Thus the land share mechanism was an
attempt by
legislators to distribute the state property to formers workers of this
enterprise and other people, involved directly and indirectly in this
enterprise or living in the village, where the enterprise had operated.
Employees
of former state agricultural enterprises, employees of enterprise of
social
infrastructure and retired workers were entitled to obtain a share of
the
farm’s land and the assets of their enterprises, which were firstly
mentioned
in the farm legislation of 1992. This land and assets shares may be
identified
physically or may remain as a paper shareholding depending upon the
choices of
the employee and the corporate nature of the privatised enterprise.
The
average size of land share was determined by dividing the total land
area of an
agricultural enterprise by the number of those entitled. The right to a
land
share was determined by the privatized enterprise which presented a
list of
those entitled to the head of local administration. Once approved, the
list was
used by the regional branch of Land State Committee to issue land share
certificates, which represented a nominal right to obtain a land plot
of state
or collective enterprise owned agricultural land. The
final size of an individual land share
depends upon the agro-ecological zone and type of farm, but is commonly
between
20-50 hectares on the northern region whereas in the southern region,
the average
size of land share varies between 2- 15 hectares. The smallest land
shares are
those for irrigated land (4).
The
invention of the “land share” was common to many countries of the
former Soviet Union reflected some of the former rules
and principle of the socialistic system. The definition of “land share”
together
with “property share” was first mentioned in the Resolution of the
Government
(№ 633, 20, July 1993) “On Measures on Implementation of the
Presidential
Decree “On the National Program of Privatization in the Republic of
Kazakhstan
for 1993-1995 years (№ 1135, 5, March 1993)”, which specified that
rural
inhabitants may have the land and property share of state enterprise in
framework of the national program of privatization. The rural
inhabitants have
a right to own land as “collective” property and they may withdraw
their “land
share” in kind. Also, these land shares were eligible to lease,
bequeath it,
but not to sell it.The Resolution of
the Government «On approval the procedure of concession of land
share on
privatization of state agricultural enterprises” (№ 611, 10, June 1994)
allowed
sales and transference of property shares and only the concession of
the land
shares to other member of collective enterprise for using these land
shares for
agricultural production. This provision provided the safeguard the
wholeness of
agricultural property complex in collective ownership.
The Civil
Code did not specify the land shares rights as an independent legal
element
with specified attribute and right to ownership. The land legislation
made no
provision for the land share to be registered officially and only a
land share
certificate ought to be issue. This land share certificates did not
provide the
precise location of land plot with a demarcated land border and other
attributes of land plot and it provides the holder only size of land
plot. Thus
the land share existed in framework of collective enterprises and
served as a
legal arrangement for transferring the property and land from state to
private
businesses. Later an Article 82 of the 2001 Law “On Land” defined the
legal
status of land shares and it reiterated the same essence of land
sharing
mechanism that was promulgated in the early land legislation.
A huge
number of rural habitants became the land share owners since the start
of agricultural
reforms in 1991. According to the statistics approximately 2.3 million
land
share were distributed to rural people. Approximately 60 % of those
land shares
were transferred to workers of liquidated, privatized and restructured
state
enterprises and 40% to workers, serving these enterprises and living in
its
territory and pensioners.
Only a
small proportion of peasants took the opportunity to become landowners
and work
on land. Large proportions however hold the same rights for lands, but
are unable
to actually farm the land. Those people faced with the problem of how
to manage
their land shares. The number of such people has been increasing every
year due
to the retirement of older people and migration to urban area and
others
reasons. These circumstances provided the private legal entities with
possibility to lease land shares from rural habitants. This lease
agreement
provided the land share holders with lease payments, which usually are
very low
and mainly paid in kind. Also, the current land legislation did provide
the holders
of land share with the possibility of withdrawal of their land share in
order
to establish an individual farm or to pool their shares or to take the
land
plot for the establishment of partnership, co-operative or joint- stock
company.
The
division of land into shares allowed for the creation of large private
enterprises and the owners of these newly appeared enterprises were
able to
accumulate the shares of those rural habitants, who did not realise
their
rights were being used for organizing large scale business. Land share
privatization provided an opportunity for land consolidation in the
hand of
private business entities without any physical division of farmland,
thereby
allowing private businesses to retain large areas of farmland for
agricultural production.
Thus, the
distribution of land shares was an important instrument for
restructuring the
agricultural sector by transferring from state ownership into private
ownership, which is basis for a market economy and the further
development of
land relations.
2. Rural Kazakhstan
2.1 Land Resources.
In 1990
the total area of farmland in Kazakhstan was about 220 million hectares. Out
of this figure 35 million of land was cultivated and over 180 million
hectares
of steppe was utilised as grazing pasture for cattle breeding (2).
Following
land and agrarian reforms the agricultural economy suffered a deep
financial crisis
that lead to a decrease of the total area of cultivated land. Farmland
decreased in 2002 by 2,5 times in comparison with 1990 year and the
total area
of farmland is currently about 84,5 million hectares with arable land
accounting for 20,5 million hectares and the remaining land are used
for pasture and hayfields, amounting to 59
million
hectares and2 million hectares
respectively(2).
The actual area of sustained competitive
rainfed agriculture remains an unanswered question. The area of good
quality
soils is about 12 million hectares, mostly in the north of the country,
but the
area with quality soils and normally adequate annual rainfall for
arable
farming is less. The area suited to rainfed agriculture is mainly
concentrated in
the north and east. Even in these areas the expectation is that one
year in
three or four will be one of inadequate rainfall. Thus, rainfed arable
agricultural activity in Kazakhstan is not only restricted,
geographically, but faces high risks from climatic uncertainties, which
impact on
the productive capacity of farming entities (5).
The natural resource base provides the
opportunity to irrigate substantial areas of reasonable quality soils,
which is
one way of reducing production risks.In
the early 1990s Kazakhstan had 2.3 million hectares of
irrigated land, which accounted for 6 % of total sown area, yielding up
to 30 %
of crop production. Subsequently, the area of irrigated agriculture has
been
reduced to 1.2 million hectares due to water shortages and
deterioration of the
infrastructure systems and yields have fallen 1.5-2 times. Most of the
irrigated area is concentrated in the southern part of the country and
has also
undergone a contraction. The land reclamation qualities of soil have
been
deteriorating, while the technical condition of water stations has also
worsened (11).
The third natural resourcecategory is
permanent pasture (mostly steppe), which is the dominant natural
vegetation of Kazakhstan. This category covers 90% of the
country, but the quality of the pasture varies considerably depending
on soil
quality, temperature and rainfall regimes. The foothills of the
mountains and
parts of northern Kazakhstan support quality pasture but large
areas are arid and support only scrub vegetation. The scale and range
of
quality of the natural grasslands determines that livestock systems
must be the
dominant form of agricultural system over much of the country (5).
The natural environment that supports
agricultural
production systems is fragile due to past inadequate attention to
sustainable
production practices which meant that substantial areas of lands
suffered from
saline soils, water logging, soil erosion and desertification. The loss
of
quality topsoil over the past 30 years is well recognised and parts of
the
black soil area have lost up to 30% of their humus content (5).
The introduction of market norms through land
legislation has substantially
affected the reallocation of land categories in the agrarian sector.
The introduction
of private ownership, land tax and land use rights have forced
landusers to
optimise the size of their lands. The category of farmland has incurred
to
substantial changes and its land area has decreased to 136,2 million
hectares
in 2002 (2). Besides, the land tax, other reasons of land users refusal
from
land tenure were declining the sowing area due to high risks from climatic uncertainties and decrease of livestock production. Thus the return of these agricultural lands to
land reserve fund has taken place, mainly on pasture in semi-desert and
desert
area and on arable land in dry lands.The
total area of this fund has increased in 7 times
to compare with
1990 and its accounts for 127,3 million hectares as of 1, January 2002
(2).
2.2. Rural
Development Policy in Kazakhstan.
The process of agricultural reforms
in the country can be broken down into four stages. The period of
1992-1194 was
characterised by the rapid reform of agricultural entities. At this
stage the
creation of a new legal framework for privatisation and land reforms
were the
main goal of reformers, leading to the adoption of laws on land,
privatisation
and peasant farms (11).
By the end of 1994, as a result of
the privatization of collective and state agricultural enterprises the
number
of agricultural entities had increased. But, total agricultural output
did not
increase despite the establishment of alternatives forms of farming
entities
such as peasant farms and production co-operatives. The reason which
has been
described in detail above were a mixture of economic, legal and social
factors
which inhibited the efficient production and rational use of land (11).
The majority of the rural
population
were unready to accept reforms, which represented fundamental changes
in the
rural life-style (11). Existing technological links in the production
and in the
procurement of inputs and machinery were disrupted. The more serious
problem of
price disparity between industrial and agricultural products emerged as
a
direct result of government regulations whereby prices of industrial
goods and
services were liberalised whilst prices for agricultural commodities
were fixed
(4).
When agricultural prices were
finally liberalised in 1994 the higher prices led to a fall in consumer
purchasing power. Subsequently, high inflation led to the loss of
current and
partly fixed assets, mainly livestock as livestock owners slaughtered
cattle to
raise the cash. This was a starting point of rural out-migration.
The principle of continuity of
technological processes on farms, service providing farms and similarly
enterprises was broken.Several
factors
such as the accelerated privatisation of state agricultural
enterprises,
storage processing and service entities, limited business forms of
organization,
high inflation and unbalanced nature of sectors made the integration of
agriculture impossible, further reducing the efficiency of the
production
process.
The funds provided under a
framework of loan financing for newly established farms were
insufficient.
Furthermore, the state budget did not allocate additional funding for
the rural
sector in the framework of the 1991 Law ”On Prioritised Development of
Auls,
Villages and Agriculture”, which aimed to soften the consequences of
market
transition for rural economy (11).
In this way, inadequate
implementation of market reforms in agriculture from 1992-1994 led to a
fall in
agricultural output, the deterioration of the asset base and an
increase in
negative tendency in both production and social sector. It also led to
a significant
increase in the migration of the rural population to cities (11).
The period of 1995 -1997 was
characterised by an increasingly rapid fall in agricultural output due
to
declines in the cultivated area and decreasing livestock numbers and as
well as
low yield and productivity (11).
The private farms accounted for
93,5 % of all agricultural enterprises while the numbers of production
co-operatives
and agriculturalenterprises were also
increased.
Before 1992 several hundred farms were set up with sufficient resources
base,
but during “mass privatisation” in period 1993 -95 the condition of
privatisation changed and most state agricultural enterprises were
deprived of
state support, thrown into free market and found themselves in debt. A
majority
of these state enterprises were heavily indebted and employees with
property
share found themselves partly to the debt share of enterprise. In this
situation
agricultural employees were often forced to sell or transfer their land
use
rights almost unconditionally and in many cases to creditors.
The already seriously complicated
situation in the agricultural sector was exacerbated by the
transference of the
accounting system from cash methods to accrued methods by Resolution of
Government “On transition to Accrued Methods in Tax Accounting” (1001, 20
June 1997).This
resulted in the bankruptcy of many insolvent farmers, because the
income tax on
accrued method was considerable more than the actual profit, which
farmers had
at the reporting date (11).
Investments in the agricultural
sectors were substantially reduced, because of sudden policy changes
and the transition
from state distribution of investment resources to market mechanisms.
Farms
were generally not profitable and they could not get a loan from the
banking
sector due to the instability and crisis in agricultural sector.
Government
measures were very limited and not very effective. Between 1995 -1997
gross
agricultural output declined by 38 % compared with 1992-1994, a fall
made up of
a 26 % reduction in crop farming and a 55 % drop in livestock farming
output
(11).
This decline in agricultural output
inevitably caused adverse social effects. Social tension and migration
away
from rural area, particularly younger people intensified. Average wages
in
agriculture were 3,8 times lower than in industry. Social
infrastructure in the
majority of villages was inadequate and did not satisfy basic needs.
After the “optimisation”
of education and health care sectors nearly 60 % of villages lost their
medical
care stations, libraries, clubs and more 50 % of rural settlement did
not have
any post offices (2).
The period of 1998-2000 saw several
positive changes in rural life since independence. More state support
was made
available for agricultural producers and agricultural enterprises began
to
receive the favourable loans and advance payment within the state
procurement
programs. 1999 was remarkable for the fact that agricultural production
grew
for the first time in several years and growth was at 28 % compared to
1998. The
decline in the number of cattle and horses slowed, while the
corresponding
number for pigs, sheep and goats began to increase (11).
Nevertheless, agricultural
producers were still constrained by the lack of guaranteed assess to
local
wholesale food markets, the low purchasing prices for their product,
the largely
depreciated asset base, limited financing options, high taxes,
depletion of
natural resources and low consuming power. Falling living standard and
higher
unemployment rates led to an increase in “self-employment”, which
amounted to 2
million people by 2001, although whether these people were able to
provide with
sufficient income was doubtful. Increased migration led to a
significant drop
in the country’s population, including in the rural areas (11).
In 2001-2002 the government adopted
two-level grain purchasing scheme. In accordance with the Law ”On
Agricultural
Corporation and their Associations” (December of 2000)the
Agricultural Corporation was established. This corporation is 100 %
owned by the
state and is able to mandate the establishment of credit partnerships
in rural
areas. During this period the government made a number of key decisions
such as
ensuring lower prices for fuel, providing subsidies for seed-farming,
livestock
breeding, crop protection and veterinary programs (11).
In 2002 the state allocated 15,6
billion tenge for agriculture, a figure which was 1,5 billion tenge
more than
in 2001. The state portfolio of agricultural loans grew up to 12,3
billion
tenge in 2002 compared with 8,42 million tenge in 2001.
Positive changes appeared in the rural social
sector and the number of
rural settlement without a medical care facility or attendant dropped
during
2001. In the same year 70 first aid centres were re-opened, as well as
17
medical-obstetric centres and 27 rural hospitals. But, the quality of
medical
care and the resource base of rural medical centres still leave much to
be
desired. Similar problems remain in rural education and the same
measures have
been taken by the state in education and in other area of rural sector
development (11). In 2001 new secondary
schools were built in the rural area, which provided additional
12 799
places for school attendance. Regarding the pre-school institutions
only 162
additional place in rural were provided by authorities (2). Despite
that
economic development of a rural area remained the government priorities
the
President announced the National Rural Development Program for 2004-
2010 under
which the sufficient funds are supposed to allocate for creation of a
social
infrastructure in the selected rural areas.
2.3
Rural
Economy and Poverty. Kazakhstan’s population in 2002 was 14.82
million, of which 43.4 percent was located in rural areas.The relative proportion of rural and urban
populations has not changed significantly since 1989 (2). Although a
total of
approximately 600,000 rural inhabitants have moved to urban areas
between 1995-
2002.However, the shift in
population
from rural to urban areas has been relatively balanced by emigration to
other
countries from urban areas. In general, the migration process has been
characterized by the following pattern: Kazakh people migrate within
country
–mostly to regional centres such as Almaty and Astana cities; members
of other
ethnic group have tended to emigrate to their original countries such
as Russia, Germany and other countries (11). Table 1: Total and rural
population
ear
1989
1995
2002
Total
16,1992
15,9567
14,8209
Rural
population
7,063
7,069
6,472
Rural
in percentage
43,60%
44,30%
43,67%
This data represents a decline in the rural
population of approximately 0,6 million people over the past decade
while the overall
population declined by 1,4 million of people. The overall rural
population
density is low, at less than 6 persons per square kilometre while the
rural
population density is very high in the southern regions. The rural
population
densities within most oblasts reflects on the resource endowments
within these
administrative units and the area with favourable climate conditions
for
agriculture it is much higher compared with to those areas with
unfavourable
conditions.
At the end of 2003, 30.9
percent of Kazakhstan’s rural population had an income
below the minimum monthly subsistence level of 5162 KZT
(approximately$35.00). Rural
poverty is a significant issue in Kazakhstan and the Government of Kazakhstan
has taken two related approaches to address this challenge.The first is to focus on issues, which are
specific
to the rural sector, such as the provision of physical infrastructure,
health
and education, and measures to improve the viability of the local
economies,
etc.A significant number of farms are
unprofitable however more resources will be directed to those rural
settlements
that are considered to have stronger economic potential. This is both
to
maximize the return on the Government’s investment and to encourage
migration
from those settlements with less potential. The second and related
approach is
focused on the agricultural industry, which accounts for an estimated
90
percent of rural economic activity (6). Table 2
:Poverty Distribution by Oblast, 2003
Total
Urban
Rural
Akmola
16.4
10.9
20.6
Aktobe
19.0
6.8
35.5
Almaty
25.3
10.5
31.5
Atyray
32.7
25.5
44.0
West Kazakhstan
17.1
7.0
23.9
Zhambyl
30.0
21.0
36.6
Karaganda
15.1
9.0
40.1
Kostanai
21.0
9.2
34.3
Kyzyl-Orda
27.1
17.9
42.2
Mangistau
26.0
19.1
59.9
North Kazakhstan
26.1
19.2
29.8
Pavlodar
17.1
7.1
32.8
South Kazakhstan
11.9
3.8
17.0
East Kazakhstan
16.9
10.1
26.8
Astana
city
2.1
2.1
-
Almaty
city
3.9
3.9
-
Kazakhstan
19.8
10.8
30.9
This table shows the highest proportions of
population with income below the living minimum subsistence level are
seen in
Mangistau (59.9 %),Atyray (44 %),
Kyzyl-Orda(42,2 %) and Aktobe (35,5%).
These oblasts are regions with huge oil deposits and the economy of
these
regions has substantial growth and is one of the main contributors to
the GDP
of the country. Thus, impressive economic results do not always lead to
improvement in the conditions of the poor in rural areas.
Wages in
agriculture have always been lower than industry, but the gap has never
been so
significant. For example, in 1985 and 1991 agricultural workers earned
89 % and
78 % of industrial workers respectively. By 1994 this had dropped to 37
% and
compared with nation’s average salary it was 60 %. This downward trend
in
agricultural versus industrial wages has persisted, falling to 28 % in
2001, or
only 39 % of average wages nation –wide. In the last three years wages
in
agriculture remained the low. In comparison with other wages in other
sectors
agricultural wages are one fifth of salaries in the finance sector or
slightly
over 30 % in the transportation and communication sector employees. The
above
ratios are true for all regions. Recently government policy prioritised
industry development and it has led to a serious deterioration in the
living
standards of rural population and caused the migration of significant
number of
the younger and working age population to the cities (11).
3.
Implementation of
Land Reform
3.1. Land Reform Concept.
The Land Code of 2003 establishes two form of
land ownership for agricultural land –private land ownership and land
possession under temporary or permanent land use rights. In addition,
the Land
Code recognises equal protection for state and private land ownership.
This
Land Code provided the legal framework for land privatization and its
conversion into tradable commodities. The owner of land has the right
to
possess, to use and to dispose of their own land at their own
discretion and
will. The definition of “private ownership for land’ by Land Code is
the ability
to possess, to use and dispose of a land plot on the base, conditions
and
limits, established by land legislation. This definition complies with
the principle
of ownership within Roman Law and consequently with Kazakh civil
legislation.
The
legislation stipulates the following ways that private ownership for
land can
arise: -acquiring
a land plot on the basis of legal state acts through purchase of the
land plot from the state; -acquisition
of land plot under deals, stipulated by civil legislation such as purchase
from private land owners, donation and concession of ownership right; -acquiring a land plot via inheritance or the
re-organization of legal entities.
The purchase of a land plot for
private
ownership from the state could be made in the following ways: purchase
of a land
plot according to its cadastre value (assessed), acquisition of plot on
delayed
payment and at the reduced prices by lump sum or by delayed payment for
10
years. All those three methods should be based on the cadastre value of
land
plot.
The Land Code gives the priority for purchasing
state owned agricultural land to rural residents, who will conduct
farming by their
own actions and who have specific agricultural knowledge and experience
in
working with land plot. Citizens and legal entities have the right to
buy land at
the reduced prices in size of 75 percent of cadastre value, established
by
Government Resolution. In case of purchase of land for ten years the
land could
be used as collateral after 50 percent of the purchase price has been
paid with
only the repaid amount of land being pledged as collateral.
The Code also establishes the maximum size of
land plot that can be purchased, something which varies from region to
region.
The following limits of maximum size of land plot established: for the
citizen
of Kazakhstan – from 30 hectares up to 25 000 hectares, including
irrigated land – from 1 hectare up to 1400 hectares; for non-state
legal
entities and its affiliated entities-from
150 hectares up to 240 000 hectares
including irrigated land-
from 5 hectares up to 19 000 hectares.
Explicit criteria for determining of maximum
sizes of land plot were not incorporated in the land legislation. Most
probably
the government established the maximum size of a land plot on the basis
of
prevailing peasant farms size in the regions.
The land
legislation establishes the permanent use rights for state legal
entities and
temporary land use rights for non-state legal entities, citizens and
international organizations. The land use right is the ability to
possess use and
secure benefits in various forms on the basis of the lease contract.The granting of land use rights to legal
entities and citizens is decided by the local executive body. Land use
right can
arise in the following ways: -acquiring
land plot by leasing land directly from the state; -acquiring land by concluding lease contract
with private owners of land plots; -acquiring land use rights through universal
assignments
such as inheritance or there-organization
of legal entities.
In
accordance with Land Code the land use could be: -temporary
land use on paid
basis, which might be: - short-term up to 5 years; - long-term up to 49 years. -temporary
land use on non-paid basis not exceeding 5 year as land plot for civil servant
and employees of state enterprises, determined by Government Resolution; -permanent
land use, granted to needs of
state landusers.
3.2. Procedure of Land
Allocation and Entitlement.
The Land
Code specifies the procedure for land allocation both for private
ownership and
under temporary land use right for 49 years. In both cases, those
interested
must submit their applicationto
local
executive body with their application, containing the following
information: -purpose of land plot use; -proposed size of land plot ; -location of land plot; -requested type of land ownership; -presence
of other land plot, granted to private ownership without payment.
The application should be considered within
three
months from time of actual acceptance of the application. By the order
of the
local executive body the regional Agency for Land Resources Management
should determine
whether the request is in conformity
with territorial
zoning and should organize the preliminary search for a suitable land
plot. Then
the proposal should be considered by the committee, which could be
created by the
local executive body and made up of local deputies, representatives of Agency for Land
Resources Management and other state agencies and persons, appointed by
the executive
local body.
The decision concerning the land plot should be
sent to the applicant during seven days after the decision has been
made. Any refusal
to grant land must be supported by full and written reasons. Following
a decision
to grant land the regional Agency for Land Resources Management should
prepare
the contact for land purchase and receive payment. This contract for
land
purchase should become the official basis for issuing the legal
documents and
be accepted as proving the land right.
The physical identification of the land plot
shall
be implemented by specialised legal entities and citizens, who are
licensed to
carry out such work. The work on physical identification of land plot
comprises
the initial elaboration of the land plot scheme and a strict definition
of the
land plot with demarcated border and other land attributes and finally
execution
of the project with all attendant documentation. The use of land before
the defining
of the land plot is not permitted and violation of this provision is
subject to
administrative remedies.
The legal documents, that establish land use
right are provided by the state Agency for Land Resources Management.
These
documents together with the land project, prepared by specialised legal
entities, should be presented to the regional state agency for
registration of
real estate and deals. After checking all documents, proving the land
use right
this agency shall register private ownership right. In accordance with
current
registration, any rights on the property and other ownership should be
registered and will come into force after this registration. Thus, the
land use
right will be certified by legal act in the form of a deed, which
should be registered.
In addition, this agency records all other encumbrances on the land
such as
mortgage, leases and other restrictions, thereby showingcomplete inventory of legal rights on the
land.
The Land Code provides provisions for acquiring
land into the private ownership in cases where it is currently used for
agricultural production under temporary land use right. In this case,
the
applicant should submit additional documents, such as the dead of
temporary
land use right, a copy of business registration certificate, inquiry
from tax
inspectorate on absence of debts, inquiry from the centre for
registration of
real estate and deals. The regional land state committee should
identify the
land plot, determine the cadastre (assessed) value of land and prepare
the
draft of decision about granting private ownership on land plot.This decision should be made within one month
period from the date of applying.
The granting of land plot for private ownership
or under temporary land use right for the creation of peasant farm is
considered in this Land Code. In addition to the documents listed
previously the
applicant should also submit a brief program of the proposed farming,
documents, proving the work experience of the peasant farm head in
agricultural
production and relevant agricultural education, copy of taxpayer
certificate
and address of the head of peasant farm. The document, proving the
right to the
land plot should be given to the head of the peasant farm with a list
of names
of all the member of the peasant farm.
The Land Code also provides an opportunity to
receive
land plot for private ownership or temporary land use right, when it is
currently occupied by agricultural entities under lease contract. The
application of citizen concerning the withdrawal of land under use by
an agricultural
enterprise should be submitted to this agricultural enterprise and
considered
within one month if the citizen applied before sowing or after the
completing
harvesting. In some cases receiving a land plot from the agricultural
enterprise will only be possible with the consent of the agricultural
enterprise. Thus, legislation defends the right of the agricultural
producer to
refuse to cede land plot, which was sowed by them. The legislation does
not
guarantee the right of citizens to land from the agricultural
enterprise and
there are no particular provisions to ensure that plot applicant are
given good
plots of land.Even if these applicants
are and share holders they do not have any right for certain plots of
land plot
because their land shares do not specify the location of land plot, but
only
their size.
The local executive body does not consider such
application and thus decisions to grant land should be made on the
basis of
land location project and with the consent of agricultural enterprises.
All
disputes arising may be considered by the court. However, these appeals
to
court do have their own limitations. Court procedures are costly and
take significant
amounts of time before a decision is made. Court trials are not the
best solution
for citizens, wishing to get land plot from agricultural enterprise.
The Land Code contains some provisions, which
secure the right of members, who possess the land plot under “joint
ownership”,
which means possession of land by two or several owners. Such members
have the
right to exit the collective with a physical land plot, corresponding
to the
individual share of collective property. It will not be possible in
cases when the
land plot is not divisible and the person, who exits the collective can
sell
their land share to outside people. But before doing this he/she should
notify
the other members of the collective in writing concerning this deal and
those
people have priority on purchasing this land share. Division of land
plot under
collective ownership should be made after a preliminary decision
determining
the land share of each member. The provisions of Land Code establishes
a
mechanism for transferring land from joint ownership to private and
guarantees
the individual’s freedom of choice.In
such a way, individuals are entitled to leave the collective taking
their share
of land with them.
3.3. Restrictions
on the
Rights of Landowners and Landusers.
The Land
Code establishes the following basis for termination of land ownership
or land
use right: -alienation
of land plot or use right by another entities; -voluntary
refusal of landowner from their private ownership or landusers from their land use right; -deprivation
of ownership and land use right in
accordance with existing legislation.
Ownership
rights and land use right can also be withdrawn by following cases: -presence of claim from creditors; -compulsory
purchase for state needs; - deterioration
of land andenvironment and use of land
for not specified
purpose ; -when
land has been subject to radioactive pollution; -confiscation
by the decision of the court on
criminal offences.
Land use rights could
also be terminated by the expiry of a term of granting land plot or
lease
contract.
The Land Code regulates
land use and land relations in order to further the rational and
effective use
of land and also, because the land is considered a natural resources
rather
than simply an asset. The
Code gives priority to land protection as a necessary component for the
safe
use of land in agricultural production. The owners of land plot can
possess,
use and freely dispose with land plots, but their rights can be
terminated by
non-sanctioned changes of use or following infringements, which cause,
damage
and deterioration in the quality of land. In such cases, the regional
Agency
for Land Resources Management brings a suit to court and the decision
to withdraw
land will be made by the court. Landowners have the right to defend
their right
in court.
The Land Code intends to defend the public
interest in land relations. A number of provisions provide individuals
and
legal entities with opportunities to own a land plot. However, the Land
Code also
restricts the rights of owner in case of conflict with public interest.Land can be withdrawn from private hands by
means of compulsory purchase in the following cases: to meet
international
commitments; for needs of defence, park zone or recreational centre;
where minerals
are found under the land; for the construction of roads, infrastructure
building
and related installation.
In accordance with the Land Code in these cases
the state should buy the land at a price, agreed with the owner of the
land
plot. If the owner refuses to sell their land plot at a reasonable
price, the local
executive body has the right to bring a suit to court regarding the
purchase price.
Land legislation gives priority to the local executive body rather than
the land
owners when it comes to determining the price for the plot sought for
public
needs.
The Land Code establishes certain restrictions
on the acquisition of land plot into ownership in particular foreign
citizens
and entities are not permitted to buy either land of agricultural value
and
non-agricultural land. The land legislation does allow foreign citizens
and
person without citizenship to receive a land plot of agricultural value
under temporary
land use rights for 10 years.
In accordance with Government Resolution
citizens
and legal entities have the right to buy land at 75 percent of cadastre
value.
But in this case the new owner will not able to make any deals normally
allowed
by civil legislation for a period of 10 years. These owners can only
pledge their
land plot as collateral. The same restriction applies to owners of
land, who
bought land plot on a delayed payment for 10 years either at the basic
price or
reduced prices. As regards pledging as collateral they have right to
pledge both
as collateral after repayment of 50 percent of land cadastre value and
only on the
repaid amounts in both cases. The landowners are also restricted from
any deals
with their land except using it as collateral unless they repurchase
the land
use right from the state.
3.4. Restrictions to Land
Shares Owners.
The previous land legislation envisaged that
some
land shares will be given for lease to legal entities and peasant farms
and
consequently land plots, which were intended to allocate among the
owners of
land share would be cultivated by leasehold owners. According to the
Agency on Land
Resources Management of 1, January 2004 about 628.6 thousands land
shares were given
to legal entities and peasant farms under lease contract, covering a
total area
of 26.3 million hectares. Approximately 60 percent of these land shares
are located
in northern regions, where the cereal productions prevail due to the
climatic
conditions (7).
In order to ensure a prompt
transition to private
ownership for agricultural land the Land Code contains Transitional
Provisions,
which had the effect of imposing certain restrictions on land shares
and land
use rights. These provisions are as follows: -citizens
of Kazakhstan and non-state legal entities who lease their land
plot to secondary users are obliged to
cancel
these lease contract (sub-lease) by 1st January 2005; -holders
of land shares, who lease their land shares for lease are obliged
to realize their rights until 1, January of
2005 on term and conditions established by
legislation.
The
owners of land shares hold the rights for realization of their rights
under
this Land Code. In particular,
the right for a land share must be realised by one of the following
methods: -
purchase of
the land plot for private ownership; - acquiring
the land plot for joint or individual land use for farming or
agriculturalproduction;
- transfer by means
of a contribution to the statutory
fund of partnership or otherlegal entities.
Granting land by
land shares is
made under the general
procedures of land allocation. Once land ownership or land use right
has been
granted previous contracts such as lease contract for the land plot or
lease
contract for a land share are considered repealed. If the owners of the land
shares do not fulfil
one of listed options for realizing their rights they will forfeit the
right to
a land share and the “virtual land” will be transferred to a special
local land
fund by decision of the local executive body. Citizens
and non-state legal entities, who possess the land plot under temporary
land
use right, have the following right to: -purchase
of the land plot for private ownership; -acquiring
the land plot for joint or individual land use for farming or
agriculturalproduction; -transfer
by means of a contribution to the statutory fund of partnership or otherlegal
entities.
If the landuser does not fulfil one of listed
options for realising their rights under land tenure the cancellation
of the sub-lease
contract and the termination of temporary land use right will be
ordered by of
a court procedure following application by the regional Agency for Land
Resources Management. Following such a decision their land plot will be
transferred to special local land fund by the decision of a court.
The owners of land shares may transfer these to
farming entities by creating an informal partnership on the basis of a
contract
of joint business activity. In the first stage, the owners of land
share must
submit their application to the legal entity, where they have decided
to place their
land shares.
In the second stage the legal entities must
make a decision to change their charter because of the appearance of
new
participants. The decision to change a charter must be taken by
authorised
bodies such as the general meeting of member of the production
cooperative,
general meeting of participants in the partnership or for joint stock
companies
a general meeting of shareholders. On the decision of these authorised
bodies
the business entities must prepare the relevant legal documents and
identify
the participation of new members in their business. In case of
partnership the
additional contract must be signed by both parts. In all business
entities
amendments to their charter must be made and it should reflect changes
in the numbers
of participants.
In the third stage an evaluation of these land
shares ought to be performed by an assessment of auditors or by
agreement
between the parts.The Land Code does
not specify exactly how the assessment of land share could be made. The
manual
on Land Code, prepared by the Research Centre under Presidential
Administration
only recommended some procedure for evaluating land shares.
In the fourth stage the land project of these
business entities should be checked by the state Agency for Land
Resources
Management. The executive state body will make a decision regarding the
granting of the land plot to this business entity.Then land plot will be physically allocated
and all State Acts (deeds) for land use will be given to this business
entity.
Finally, registration of this business entity
should be made in oblast branches of Ministry of Justice. The share
issuance must
be made for joint stock companies.
3.5.Land Payment
Despite the fact that agricultural land was
given to farmers for temporary land use without any payment, the land
plots under
temporary land use are subject to land tax in accordance with the Tax
Code. The
Tax Code (12th, June 2001) establishes two tables of tax
rates based
on the variability of land quality across the regions. The first table
is
relevant to land on the steppe and dry steppe with usual and southern
chernozem, chestnut and dark-chestnut soil and piedmont area with
chernozem,
dark gray soil and chestnut. The second table covers all other types of
land,
including semi-desert, desert and dry piedmont areas with all type of
soils in
those areas. The range within the first table, containing the more
favourable lands
for agriculture varies between 0,48 tenge per 1 hectare for the lowest
quality
of land to 202,65 tenge per hectar for the
highest quality of land soil. Tax rates for the majority of lands for
agricultural production are within a tax range of 14 tenge and 34 tenge
per
hectare. The range of the second table varies between 0,48 tenge per 1
hectarefor the lowest quality of land
and 50,18 tenge per hectare for the highest quality soil.
This land payment applies to land plot, which
have
been allocated for temporary use under lease. Lease payments are linked
to land
taxes and the annual lease rate is determined by Resolution of
Government (No
890, 2, September of 2003) within the range of 100-120 percent of basic
rate of
tax payment for land. The size, condition and the schedule of payment
of the lease
contract is determined within the actual contract, but the size of the
lease
payment should not exceed this established range.
The cadastre value is determined by the regional
state Agency for Land Resources Managements on the basis of base
payment rates
for land plots. They were established by a Resolution of Government of
Republic
of Kazakhstan (No 890, 2nd, September, 2003) and depend on the type of
farmland
and the actual regional location. The base rates of payment for land
are
established per hectare and differentiated by type of land soil.
The basic rates of payment for
land vary in the
following ranges at the current exchange rate 130 tenge to 1 USD as of
1.06.05: - arable land -between 60 USD and 428 USD; -irrigated
land -between244
USD and 1572 USD; -hay
field -between 24 USD and 139 USD; -pasture –
between13 USD and 98 USD.
3.7.
Deficiencies Identified
in the Land Code.
The land legislation being a comprehensive set
of legal and normative acts, embracing all aspects of land relations,
has some
disputable provisions. One such provision, which provokes disputes and
disagreements among politicians and land specialists, is the
regulation, cancelling
sub-lease agreements. A second disputed provision concerns the owners
of land
shares who according to the relevant provisions have to make a decision
on
their land share. In both cases the last date is 1 January
2005.
The land reform is one complicated part of
agrarian reform and it usually takes a significant amount of time to
implement a
new law and many factors determine the speed of land reform. The Land
code
itself is a whole legal framework with complicated institutional and
financial
aspects that themselves exert a significant influence over the progress
of land
reforms. Social and historical factors are also a key issue and land
reforms in Kazakhstan have proved this the case. When the legislators
introduce the next legislative acts in the form of laws and
presidential
decrees the peasants could not response immediately. It takes time for
the
rural population to make adequate decisions and act on the proposal and
regulation, established by land legislations. For example, the result
of the land
reforms proposed by the Law “ On Land ”
of 1995 only became visible and achievable in 2001 yet the result of
this
reformwas soon cancelled out by the
introduction
of the new Law ”On land” in 2001.
In this current proposed schedule it is obvious
that many peasants will try to make a decision concerning their land or
land
shares . However, it is likely that not all of them will be able to
implement
all the necessary steps that will entitle them to the land rights.
Despite the Land
Code being promulgated on June 2003 it was not possible to implement
the land
reform, because the Land Code did not contain guidelines concerning the
procedures
for introducing these changes.The
relevant
provisions of the Land Code could be applied after the issuing of the
Manual on
Land Reform on March 2004 b y the Research Centre under Presidential
Administration. The result was that peasants have less than 9 months to
conduct
all the legal procedures, stipulated in the land and civil legislation.
Only a couple farms were able to re-register by
the end of March of 2004 as required by current legislation in Atbasar
raion of
Akmola oblast, which was a project area for conducting social and
economic
survey for this research. By the beginning of October only several
farms of
this raion have re-registered and the majority of farms in this rayon
are at the
stage of performing the legal procedures for re-registering their
farms.
Nevertheless, these farms were able to meet the dead line of 1st January
2005.
According to official
statistics the
contribution of 628.6 thousands land shares (reported as of 1 of
January 2004)
was made by the land owners in the following ways: -
contributed to the statutory fund of partnerships -44,6 percent; -
contributed to statutory fund of peasants farms-
23,2 percent; - used for
organizing
agricultural production- 17,2
percent. -
contributed to production cooperative-4 percent - unused
or refused land shares-
9,7 percent.
The latter figure revokes some
concern because
this official statistics does not provide any breakdown by more
detailed
explanation of this category. This figure shows that more 60 thousands
of rural
residents were not able to realize their right, which was given by land
share.
It might some rural residents, who were not able to manage on time with
their
land shares, in some extend it might be some so- called “morally
degrading”
people some kind of vulnerable group of people, who does not take any
cares about
own. Most likely some farms missed to meet the
deadline for official re-registration and peasants
in some remote areas with severe
conditions for crop growing had no opportunity to contribute their land
shares
to a farming business, because of the absence such entities. Currently,
it is
very difficult to believe to Kazakh statistics now, particularly on
some
sensitive issues such land relations, even this published data does not
give
100 percent in total (miss of 1,3 percent). In case of Atabasar raion
this data
on percentage of unused or refused land shares might be true, because
the local
branch of Agency for Land Resources Management was headed by qualified
specialist
in land relations and the region was attractive for crop growing. And it is very difficult to imagine the
situation in others regions, where crop growing is very risky due to
climatic
conditions.
Another critical point might be the cancellation
of secondary land leases, which will considerably limit the freedom of
landusers. The tenants on such land plots must start farming otherwise
they will
lose their right to the land. This provision goes against with the
civil law
principle of freedom of entrepreneurial activities. A fairer
alternative would
be to allow sub-lease for secondary landuser for terms less than their
principal agreement with the state.
At the initial stages of agricultural land
market development the lease could be serve as an alternative means for
transferring
land from less to more productive producers. In the experience of other
countries encouraging of land rental markets coincides with measures to
reduce
the credit and insurance market imperfection in rural areas. The high
risk in
agricultural production in rural Kazakhstan means that the development of both
these markets is hampered. Alongside increasing the productivity of
agricultural production leasing land could be cautious step for tenant
farmers
to start business.
The majority of agricultural land remains in the
possession of non-state agricultural enterprises. These entities rent
land from
the owners of land shares and therefore these entities possess a
considerable
part of the agricultural land, which accounts for several thousands
hectares of
agricultural land in northern regions, favourable for cereal
productions. The
Land Code aims to prevent such concentration of agricultural land in
the hand
of single owner or legal entity by establishment the maximum size of
land plot
in each raions.Some owners of
enterprises or legal entities have land in possession in various
regions. The
Land Code does not regulate whether legal entities or individuals can
own land
in different raions. Also, the definition of “affiliated legal
entities” is not
introduced in the Land Code. Thus the
introduced provision on maximum size of land plot does not prevent from
the
concentration of land areas in hand of certain businesses or
individuals.
A certain concern exists around the delegation
of so much power to local executive bodies, particular in the
allocation of
land to citizens and legal entities. In Kazakhstan, the process of state governance
and local management is not transparent and as a result the local
executive
bodies, having powers in local management, may make a decision
according to its
own discretion. The Land Code gives the right to local executive body
the right
in land allocation and yet the legislation does not stipulate the
grounds on
which an application might be refused and the land legislation only
requires
that any refusal must be justified. The actual process of land plot
allocation
is important as lands in good condition and in appropriate locations
are always
in demand. An applicant may find that he
or she is refused land tenure in the requested place due to reluctance
of local
executive body to allocate this land plot. Moreover, land legislation
does not
provide any criteria for ranking applicants and it provides that the
process of
land granting became non-transparent.
Another issue that was omitted in this Land
Code is that the evaluation of land share is hampered by the absence of
real
market value of agricultural land. The recommendation of the Research
Centre under
Presidential Administration is based on a finding that the share of
land use
rights in business entities is about 20-25 percent of the statutory
fund and
they stated that in the majority of cases it is between 5-10 percent.
This
assumption is incorrect, because required capital for establishment of
a
partnership or other legal entities is considerable less than cost of
land use
rights, established by land legislation. As an example, the Research
Centre
suggested that the share of land shares should be 20 percent of total
statutory
fund of partnership, because in these cases the owners of land share
should
receive dividends at one fifth the net profit of business. All these
assumption
do not have much economic realities, because the cost of land use
rights is significant
in comparison with the actual assets of farm. But at the same time, the
land
legislation does not determine the cost of the land shares nor describe
the
procedure for land share evaluation.
The majority of those, who organized farms, who
made own cash contribution to business, secured financing from banks
and inputs
from supplier, who carried all the entrepreneurial risks associated
with
farming do not agree with the idea of comparing cost of land use rights
to the
value of the farm assets. As example, one interviewed head of farm in
neighbouring raion of the same oblast told me that he removed from
urban area
to one village and took the land under land use rights. The residents
of this
village had one option to rent out their shares to single farm, which
was not
profitable. This entrepreneur was able to organize sustainable farm and
provide
the rural residents with paid in cash work. He completely disagrees
that the
land share will take a significant share in his business.Thus, such entrepreneurs were able to get the
significant share in their business to compare with share of all other
participants with their land shares. This issue of appraising the value
of land
share is pending with no criterion even suggested by the legislators.
It is difficult to determine the market value
of land in the absence of a land market for arable land. After
introducing private
ownership on agricultural land no transaction occurred in the raion,
where the
research and the survey were conducted. It is most likely a similarly
situation
in other raions in the northern regions. The lack of any legally
established
procedure for determining market value of land and land shares allows
the
dominant agricultural entities to determine the value of land shares by
their
discretions which means at lowest cost. The value of land shares varies
from 89
tenge up to 23 852 tenge and the size of land share and quality of
soil
are the same.It emphasize that a fair
appraisal
of land share is needed, because appraisal by agreement by parts is not
always
fair and it does not correspond to the economic costs of a land share.
4. Social and Economic
Analysis of Rural Area.
4.1. Demographic
Profile of Rural Residents.
The average size of a rural family in the
country is about 4, 4 persons and approximately 48 percent of all
families
consist of between four and five persons (12). Small families with one
or two
persons, which are basically families without children and families of
elderly
people over 60 years of age, account for 31 percent. This is
significantly
higher than the number of households with three persons, which accounts
for 20
percent. The families with four and five and more persons amount for 22
percent
and 26 percent, respectively (2). This data shows that the demographic
profile
of rural areas has significant number of rural households with small
number of
family member, which is about 51 percent. The main reason for such a
demographic structure is out migration by young people from rural area
to
cities and urban areas.
Most family members are adults (58,3 %) of
normal working age, which is between the age of 19 and 60, youth under
the age
of 19 account for 31,4 percent of family members and elderly people
account for
10,3 percentin the country as of1stJanuary
2002 .The proportion of households with
one and two
children accounts for 45
and 34 percent relatively while households with three and four children
account
for 14 and 7 percent, respectively. In other words this data shows that
the majority
of rural families have one or two children (2).
The number of male and female in the rural
population
is approximately equal - 49, 9 percent is male and rest female. The
head of
household is male in 61 % of cases and female in 39 % of cases. Women
are
reported as head of household where families are without males or males
of
normal working age and where other males are either minors or seniors
(12).
Among adults of normal working age, a
considerable
number of these are employed by the local farm enterprise. The
percentage of males
employed is considerably higher than the percentage of females employed
on the
farm. The main occupations of females who work in the village are
social
services, teachers, medical personnel or staff of the local
administration. In
rare cases, agricultural farms employ the females on their ancillary
production
facilities. The official statistic of employment concerning agriculture
looks very
unrealistic, reporting that the rate of employment account for 92,6
percent in
rural areas in Kazakhstan (3).A certain
number of males in the rural areas are
engaged in agricultural production on a permanent basis, but not all of
them.
And only a small number of females are involved in any employment. The
high
rate of employment most likely comes from the way of official reporting
that
considers the unemployed rural people as a category of people engaged
in self- production
activities. The presence of cattle or a subsidiary land plot is a
crucial factor
for considering them as employed workers.
4. 2.Comparative
Analysis of Households Income.
The size of the household budget varies
according
to the number of adults, but it is more affected by the status of
adults. Highest
earning usually are found in families where both adults have employment
in
state organisations whereas the lowest level of income is relevant to
pensions
and families, where the adults do not have permanent employment. The
structure
of income according to the main categories of household is presented in
the following
table.
ncome items
Budget of local servants
Budget of pensioners
Budget of employed workers by farms
Budget of unemployed on permanent base
Income from land plot
12
500
4,7%
6
500
3,9%
12
500
5,3%
18
500
13,3%
Livestock product
30
000
11,3%
5
000
3,0%
35
000
14,9%
75
000
53,8%
Salary
204
000
76,8%
168
000
71,6%
Pensions
134
400
81,5%
Income from lease of share
19
000
7,2%
19
000
11,5%
19
000
8,1%
19
000
13,6%
Other income
27
000
19,4%
Total
265
500
100%
164
900
100%
234
500
100%
139
500
100%
It should be noted that
employment in the local
state organizations provides the family with a 21 percent higher income
than
employment in agricultural farms and pensioners get approximately 18
percent
more income compared with those rural people, who do not have permanent
employment.
4.3. Budget of Rural
Households.
The structure of the average household budget
for 2003 in Atbasar rayon, where the survey was conducted, is shown
below.
Household annual budget for 2003
No
Items
in tenge
In USD
in percentage
Revenue
1
Income
from land plot
12 500
89,3
6%
2
Income
from sales of livestock products
36 250
258,9
18,0%
3
Salary
from employment
93 000
664,3
46,2%
4
Pensions
33 600
240,0
16,7%
5
Rent
payments
19 000
135,7
9,4%
6
other
income, including temporary employment
6 750
48,2
3,4%
Total
201 100
1 436,4
100%
Expenditures
1
Expenses
for crop growing
1 200
9
0,6%
2
Expenses
for cattle breeding
14 000
100
7,0%
3
Utilities
34 000
243
16,9%
4
Food
104 500
746
52,0%
5
Clothes
37 700
269
18,7%
6
Expenses
on children education
2 000
14
1,0%
7
Consumer
goods
2 500
18
1,2%
8
Purchase
of cattle
0
0
0,0%
9
Purchase
of other means of production
0
0
0,0%
10
Taxes
500
4
0,2%
11
Other
expenses
900
6
0,4%
Total expenses
197 300
1 409
98,1%
Deficit or surplus
of budget
3 800
27
The average household income in the sample is
about 1430 USD in 2003 and the family derive its income mainly from
wages, their
household plots and rent payments. Some households have additional
income from the
sales of cattle and other animals. The wage income and the sales of
meat are
primarily cash while the rent payments usually are paid in kind. The
output
from the household plot output is consumed by them as foodstuffs,
because the
household plot is mainly used for growing potatoes, vegetables.
The salary is considered as the main source of
farms
income and it accounts for nearly 46, 2 percent of their total income.
The share
of income from the sales of livestock products and pensions is about 18
percent
and 17 percent, respectively. The income
from lease payments accounts for less than 10 percent of the total
household
income. The main products, which received as payment in kind, are
grain, animal
feed, hay, flour and bread, but the rural residents prefer to get
animal feed,
hay and forage as payment in kind in order to feed their household
cattle,
sheep and other animals.
The largest items of
household expenditure are the expenses for food, clothes and utilities
and they
account for 52 percent, 18,7 percent and 16,9 percent of total
household income
respectively. The food expenses comprise
the cash and non-cash expenses, which
is mainly livestock product and vegetables from a subsidiary land plot.The category of utility items includes the
expenses
for electricity and the purchase of coal, wood for heating their house
during
cold periods. Only employed workers and civil servants can afford to
pay for the
education of their children and the purchase of consumer goods and on
average
these amounts are small.
Expenses for cattle breeding and vegetable growing are mainly non-cash
expenses, which are made in kind and rarely, rural people can afford to
buy
seeds for vegetables to grow on their subsidiary land plot.
The average household
budget shows saving to the amount of 3800 tenge (approximately 27 USD
at rate
of 2003 end). The level of actual spending is 98,1 percent of the totalincome and it emphasises that the rural
residents
have only small amounts of saving and they spend almost all their
incomes in
order to cover the basic needs for food, clothes and appropriate living
conditions. The families with higher incomes can afford to make
expenses for
education of their children and purchase of consumer goods, but the
number of
such households is insignificant. In this regard rural residents have
only
little savings, because they need spend most of their incomes on
consumption.
4.4. Identified
Social
and Economic Problems in Rural Area.
The conducted survey in Atabasar raion of
Akmola oblast, in an area of cereal production, is an attempt to assess
the recent
significant changes in rural life and to investigate the scale of
problems
faced by the rural residents in the period of political and economic
changes in Kazakhstan. This survey is aimed to assess the economic
and social problems in rural areas based on people’s perception and
expert
opinions. The sociological survey of rural raions, conducted by UNDP in
2002 identified
several serious issues such as environmental problems (37 % of
respondents),
limited prospects for youth (41 %), access to drinking water (59,2 %),
the poor
status of roads (70,3 %) and unemployment (83 %) (12). Except for the
poor
status of roads these abovementioned problems were all expressed by
rural
residents during this survey. The roads in this area are in a good
condition
compared with other rural raions of Kazakhstan and the problem with drinking water
was mentioned in the survey by residents of one village in the Atbasar
raion.
The methodology of the survey was based on the
principle
of random selection.According to this
principle each tenth rural resident was interviewed by interviewers in
two
different counties. Rural residents of various ages, occupations and
professions,
responded to the questions. Some questions received very similar
answers and
others were answered differently by the respondents. In general, the
answers of
interviewed rural residents allow some conclusion to be made concerning
social
and economic issues in the rural areas and identifying the problems
faced by rural
residents during the period of transformation of rural economy from the
Soviet
system to the market economy.
The general profile of survey
respondents is the
following: -Men
make up 58 % of the survey respondents, -80 %
of the survey respondents are of working age, while 20 % are pensioners. The
working age respondents consist of workers of private farms (48 %), employee
of state financed local organizations (2 %), self-employed workers (10 %) and unemployed respondent (20%). -All respondents hold a land share certificate.
In addition, the breakdown of survey
respondents by age group presented below:
Age
N =120
20-29
18 %
30-39
14 %
40-49
26 %
50-59
18 %
60-69
16 %
70 and older
8 %
The 40-49 year-old group contains the highest
percentage, followed by the 20-29 and 50-59 year old age groups. Some
survey
respondents in the 20-29 years-old group received land share
certificate as a bequest
from deceased relatives. All these respondents contributed their land
share
into the statutory fund of partnerships.
The UNDP sociological survey of rural areas
showed
that the rural residents incurred to poverty. This poverty situation in
rural Kazakhstan is conditioned by many factors:
economic recession, decline in real wages, increased unemployment
rates,
deteriorating social benefits, low income and increasing inequality.
According
to the survey of poor households “Causes and Conditions of Poverty in
Kazakhstan for 2002” conducted by the state statistical agency, the
main
reasons for poverty are the following: low wages (43,7% of
respondents),
inability to secure sustainable employment at the place of residence
(17 %), no
jobs at all (13%), lack of employment (7,5 %), presence of dependents
(5,4 %),
poor health status (4,1 %).
In the survey, conducted in Atbasar raion, the
respondents reported on question concerning well being in the following
ways.
Level of rural
residents well being.
Response of
survey respondents
Low
income not sufficient even for adequate nutrition
13,1%
Earned
income provides for food only with other basic needs being largely
unmet
14,8%
Earned
income provides for adequate nutrition, purchase of necessary clothes
and footwear butit is not enough to pay
for services
42,6%
Needs
of adequate nutrition, clothing footwear and buying services are met to
a certain extent
21,3%
Earned
income is enough for adequate nutrition, clothing footwear and buying
services and for purchase of some consumer goods.
8,2 %
No
financial problems
0
The result of the survey shows that about 15 %
of
rural respondents earn incomes that cover only their needs in food and
are not
enough to meet other needs. About 42
percent of rural respondent have incomes, which are enough for meeting
needs in
nutrition, clothing and footwear, but are not enough for paying for
services.
Only around one fifth of respondents are able to buy services to some
extent
and about 8 percent of respondents are able to buy some consumer goods.
Regarding the causes of poverty 74 % of
respondents reported that main causes of poverty are low salaries.
Other causes
of poverty are the following:absence of
permanent work (56 %), no jobs at all (16 %), poor health status (14%),
absence
of any social aids (36%), not enough educational background (8 %) and
unfavourable condition of living place such as poor economy of region
or environmental
problems (6%). Some respondents indicated two or three causes, but on
average
all respondent identified, at least two reasons of poverty. Respondents
of
working ages below 50 years old reported that the main cause of poverty
is low
salaries and the absence of permanent work and in some cases absence of
any
jobs. For female respondents and pensioners reported the main cause of
their
bad financial status is the absence of any social aids and poor health
status.
Correspondingly, the main factors that would,
according to respondents of working ages, improve their financial
status are
increased wages and permanent work (in both cases 78% of respondents).
Respondents were asked to select up to three possibilities that would
contribute
to improving their financial status. The third option for this group
varies from
the necessity of securing initial capital for opening own business (22
%), improving
the possibility to get credit (40%) to the importance of receiving a
land plot
into private ownership and land use right (10 %). The oldest
respondents reported
that main factors that would improve the financial status were
increased
pensions (24 %), improvement of medical care (32 %) and increase of
social aids
(20%).
Approximately half of respondents (48 %)
expressed the opinion that they would not foresee any changes in their
financial status and further one fifth of respondents believed that
their
financial status would improve only insignificantly.Only a very small group of respondents (4%) is
optimistic, believing that their financial status would improve
significantly.
The remaining part of respondents (32 %) had difficulties in answering
this
question.
Regarding the expected ways of improving
financial
status the majority of respondents (90 % of respondents) stated that
they
believed in their own power, while the oldest respondents indicated
applied
that is improvement with the help of relatives and friends (42 % of
total
responses). Some of the youngest respondents believed that the deputies
and
heads of local executive bodies would help in improving their financial
status,
in both cases 6 % of responses.
The survey showed that the rural areas face
serious problems and future prosperity is not visible unless the
government
undertakes measures to ensure the economic development of the rural
areas.
Regarding the future perspectives of their villages the respondents
responded
differently and negatives responses prevailed in their answers.
Approximately, 31
percent and 40 percent of respondents reported that the number of rural
residents steadily would steadily decline and the village would not
have any
future perspectives respectively, while 27 percent of respondents
reported that
village did have the opportunity for development of agricultural
production.
Only 2 % of rural respondent believes that the future of their village
will be good
for rural residents.
The main problem for rural areas is out
migration
of rural residents. The main reasons for this are the absence of work
opportunities
in the rural areas (92 % of responses) together with the lack of money
for starting
their own business (64% of responses). Only a few respondents (4%)
indicated
that the unsatisfactory condition of school, medical establishment and
poor
services were the reasons for rural out migration.
Almost all residents
(94 % of respondents) consider the main obstacle to the development of
their
villages is the absence of initial funds for further growth of
agricultural
production. Only a few respondents (6 %) reported that the principal
obstacles
are remoteness from the main automobile roads, the low fertility of
land and
remoteness of markets for sales of agricultural commodities.
4.5. Attitude of Rural People to PrivateLand Ownership and Land
Shares.
The
survey was intended to get some idea regarding the perception of rural
residents on private ownership of agricultural land.The survey showed that rural residents accept
the private ownership for agricultural land with two thirds of
respondents
expressing a positive attitude towards private ownership. Only 16 % of
respondent responded negatively towards the introduction of private
ownership,
while another 18 % of respondents had difficulties in answering this
question.
It is necessary to note that when the respondents were asked about what
type of
land tenure should be used for agricultural land only 26 % of
respondents stated
that private land ownership with the right to sale was appropriate.
More than
half of respondents (58 %) stated that ownership should be in the form
of lifetime
inheritable land tenure. Some respondents (12 % of respondents) had the
opinion
that agricultural land should remain under state ownership with 4 % of
respondents finding difficulties in answering this question.
Rural
residents were asked by the survey about their desire to receive a land
plot.
Two third expressed the desire to secure land tenure for land plot. Out
of
these respondents only one third stated that they would prefer to get
the land
tenure in the form of private land ownership whereas two thirds would
prefer to
receive use right for the land plot. About 33 % of respondents declared
that
they did not want a land plot. The most frequent explanations were old
age and
inability to work the land. In addition, those respondents, engaged in
employment with state bodies, stated they would not desire to get the
land
tenure.
All
those
respondents that were owners of a land shares were asked about the
obstacles to
securing land tenure for agricultural land. The respondents were
allowed to
indicate more than one reason. The vast majority (90 % of respondents)
stated
that the absence of money is the main obstacle to getting a land use
right or
purchasing land plot into private ownership. The other answers were
following:
lack of time and money for travel to raion and oblast centrefor getting a title for land (2 % of
responses); complicated procedure for getting land tenure (10% of
responses); unaware
of procedure for getting land tenure (12%).
Only 42
%
of respondents believe that the process of providing new titles for
land will
contribute to the growth of family welfare. Correspondingly, 4 % and 14
% of
respondents answered significantly and insignificantly improvement.Only 2% of respondents answered negatively
concerning
possible improvements in their family financial status while 36 % of
respondents had difficulties in answering the question. From this data
it might
be concluded that rural residents do consider land ownership as a means
improving
their financial status although the actual receipt of land for either
private
ownership or under use right will not provide substantial benefits.
The land
share owners are rural residents of various ages, social statuses and
professions, who are unable to enter independent farming and so who
look to rent
out their land shares to agricultural enterprises. The current
legislation
allows to owners of land shares to do this. The respondents were asked
their
opinion concerning the importance of lease contract for family income.
The
survey showed that many rural respondents (56 %) expressed their
dissatisfaction with the term and conditions of their lease contract
for land
shares. Less than half of respondents (40 %) stated that they consider
the
lease payment as important source of family income and while 4 percent
of
respondent had difficulties in answering.
The
survey asked the respondents about the importance of lease payments
compared
with total incomes. The result was that (56%) stated that income from
the land
share lease is less than 10 percent of the total family income. For
another group
of respondent (34 %) income from land share lease account for 10
percent of
total income whilst 10 percent stated that lease payments are equal to
15
percent of the total family income.
Another
way to assess the income from leases is to ask whether lessees are
fulfilling
their obligations to pay for lease in the amounts agreed and to pay on
time.
The majority of respondents (92 %) stated that lessees did fulfil their
obligation on the contract in front of them while 8 % of respondents
responded
that lessees fulfilled their obligation on the lease of land shares.
A
significant
number of respondents (44 %) reported that they were not satisfied with
the
lease terms and another half of respondents stated that they were only
partly satisfied
with the lease term. Only 4 % of respondents expressed satisfaction
with the lease
terms. Mainly, it was the pensioners and elder respondents who
expressed part
satisfaction with the lease terms.
Respondents
were asked about their reasons for concluding lease contract with
agricultural
entities. The following responses were obtained: no alternative options
for
renting out the land shares (38 %), it was the sole beneficial proposal
for the
lease of the land shares (8%) and it was possibility to get benefits
from the lease
of the land shares (46 %).On the basis
of this result it is evident that not so many farming entities work in
the rural
area and that the market for leasing land shares is not competitive. A
few
farms are interested in renting land shares and they offer similar
terms of
land share lease in their proposal. It is proved by prevailing
responses on
absence of alternative options.
As one
positive sign for agriculture could be the considerable number of
operating
peasant farms and therefore the respondents were asked whether they
would
establish a peasant farm. This question is very important, because this
would
give some ideas about the future situation in the agricultural sector
in Kazakhstan.
First of
all, land share owners were asked about their future use of land if
they would receive
land tenure into private ownership or by use right. The majority of
land share
owners (74 %) intended to rent out their land plot and out of this
group a considerable
part (58 %) intended to rent out to those who would pay more. Thus the
owners
of land shares prefer to get lease payments rather than be involved in
farming.
It is explicable by the fact that many respondents are elderly or
pensioners
and they are not able to conduct private farming. Only a small numbers
of
respondents (22 %) expressed the desire to be engaged in crop growing
and only
4 % of respondents intended to use the land plot for cattle breeding.
Thus, it
is not surprising to get such a result on the desire of land share
owners to
establish peasant farm. The majority of
land share owners (67 %) responded negatively concerning the
establishment of a
peasant farm and the remaining respondents answered that they did not
know
whether they would establish peasant farm.
The
responses of land share owners showed that the main obstacle to
establishing
peasant farms is the financially burdened procedure (72 % of
respondents) and the
other main obstacle is the bureaucracy of local state bodies concerning
the registration
of peasant farm (10 %). A small group (10 %) had difficulties in
answering
while the remaining respondents gave other reasons, such as lack of
interest,
inability to work with land and elder age.
The
owners of land share owners were asked to indicate the obstacles in the
operation
of peasant farm. Respondent could indicate more than one condition and
the responses
were: -absence of financing from banks and
financial establishments (28 %); -absence of agricultural machinery and rent
of machinery (46%); -high prices for services for grain storage
and cleaning (30%); -absence of possibility to sell the grain
without intermediaries on appropriate price (44 %); and -ignorance
of modern technologies on cultivation of crop production.
Finally,
the owner of land share were asked about whether the peasant farm might
unite
to form cooperatives andunions forjoint activity in the purchase of
agricultural inputs such as seed, fuel, fertilizes, rent of
agricultural
machinery and sales of agricultural commodities. A majority (78 %)
answered
positively while only 2 % of respondents answered negatively. But 16 %
of
respondents stated that they did not know about the possibility of
uniting
peasant farms into cooperatives and union and 4 % of respondents had
difficulties in answering.
Those
who
responded positively were asked to indicate the number of persons they
would unit
with for joint work. Among these respondents approximately 51%
respondents stated
that they would unit with, at least with five farmers, 23 % and 18 % of
respondents said three persons and ten persons, respectively. The
remaining respondents
had difficulties in determining the number of participants. Thus, the
land
share owners expressed that they would be able to cooperate with other
farmers
and the most frequently mentioned ideal number of participants was five.
4.6. Conclusion on conducted survey.
The
survey showed that the distribution of land shares to rural residents
did provide
them with a meaningful benefit. Despite land share owners reporting
that they
receive an insignificant benefit from rental payment compared with
total family
income these rental payments did provide rural residents with feed and
forage
for their household’s cattle and animals. In case of the termination of
these
rental payments the rural family members, who already have low cash
incomes,
would have to buy winter feed and forage for cattle at market price or
to hire
some machinery for cutting grass and preparation of forage. These are
considerably
higher compared with lessee prices. Thus the rental payment is crucial
for
rural residents.
The
majority
of land lessees are large private enterprises and they have more
possibility to
provide the owners of land share with forage and other agricultural
commodities.
In this sense they can afford to sell the forage and hay at prices,
which are considerably
lower compared with market prices.
Due to
fact that a substantial number of survey respondents (42%) are rural
resident
of eldest ages (50 years and more) it is understandable why there were
not so
many positive responses to the questions concerning the establishment
of peasant
farms. All those people are unable to farm for various reasons such as
age,
lack of relevant knowledge and experience, absence of financial
resources and
others. But the main problem is the inability for proper work in
farming, because
many respondents worked as an ordinary worker, mainly in cattle
breeding. Thus
the lease of their land shares has been an important source of income
for a considerable
number of rural residents. The payments in kind provide them with a
meaningful
benefit that helps maintain raising livestock for own consumption and
sales as
well.
5. Analysis of
Business Environment in the Rural Area.
5.1. Characteristics of
Agriculture of Kazakhstan.
Kazakhstan’s agricultural sector has several
characteristics that are particularly
relevant to this
research. Firstly, the agricultural sector’s output dropped
substantially
after the collapse of the Soviet
Union in both livestock
production and crop growing. If the crop
production has a potentiality to growth as potential recovery of
livestock
production is still doubtful. The drop in agricultural output has had a
significant impact on rural economic conditions. For example, there was
crop
failure in Atbasar raion in 2004. This resulted to decrease of a number
of
livestock in this area, because the price for animal feed went up and
rural
residents had to sell or slaughter animals. The situation was worsened
by facts
that not all agricultural enterprises were able to repay the rent
payments in
kind, particular with animal feed and hay. The consequence of this was
the
significant increase of prices for meat at least one half time and more
in this
region in 2005. The current price for meat is on level of retail
price of
large cities such as Astana and Almaty and income of urban residents of
these
cities is not comparable with income of rural residents. Thus the rural
residents had to reduce significantly the consumption of meat and meat
products.
Secondly, the
small peasant farms and individual households produce a large
proportion of
agricultural output. The data from the National Statistic Agency
presented
below breaks down agricultural production by type of producer and
highlights in
particular the growth of peasant farms in crop production (from 3
percent in
1995 to 42 percent in 2002) and the growth of individual households in
livestock production (from 66 percent in 1995 to 87 percent in
2002). It
is most likely unrealistic that these individual households produce
such
significant proportion of Kazakhstan’s crop output, which accounts for
28
percent in 1995 and 26 percent in 2002.
Agricultural Output
by Producer (%)
Type
of agricultural producers
1995
1999
2002
Crops
Agricultural
enterprises
69.0
46.0
33.0
Peasant
farms
3.0
26.0
42.0
Households
28.0
29.0
26.0
Livestock
Agricultural
enterprises
32.0
10.0
8.0
Peasant
farms
2.0
5.0
5.0
Households
66.0
85.0
87.0
Thirdly, a
significant proportion of agricultural producers operate at suboptimal
efficiency levels. This research, conducted by Scanagri in 2003 has
shown that
83 % of total Kazakhstan’s farms operate on suboptimal efficiency
level,
including 2738 farms are located in steppe zone and it accounts for 63
% of
total farms, operating in this climatic zone. The optimal farm size
varies from
10 hectares in river flood plain up to 5000 hectares in desert area. As
regards
for cereal production the optimal size is 500 hectares in steppe area
and 200
hectares for north moist steppe and other zones, suitable for crop
growing.
Fourth characteristic
of Kazakhstan’s agricultural sector is the high proportion of
inefficient
production.The table presented below
provides
a breakdown by oblast of its proportional contribution to agricultural
production, the proportion of crops and livestock in the agricultural
output of
each oblast, and the profitability of the agricultural sector in each
oblast.
Relative
Agricultural
Performance of Oblasts
% contribution to
Share of crops to
Share of livestock
Net profit
Profit
Oblast
Total agricultural
total agricultural
To total agricultural
(In KZT
Margin
Production
output in each
output in each
million)
(%)
Oblast (%)
oblast (%)
Akmola
11.3
69.6
30.4
1396.3
9.9
Aktyubinsk
3.7
36.0
64.0
128.9
6.3
Almaty
13.5
53.5
46.5
628.9
11.2
Atyrau
1.0
18.6
81.4
41.1
11.4
E.
Kazakhstan
9.9
50.4
49.6
221.4
8.8
Zhambul
5.6
63.9
36.7
-4.5
-0.3
West
Kazakhstan
3.9
46.5
53.5
3.8
0.3
Karaganda
5.0
48.4
51.6
665.7
22.4
Kostanai
14.2
56.2
43.8
1778.3
11.8
Kyzylorda
1.9
59.1
40.9
-66.9
-3.7
Mangistau
0.2
1.5
98.5
-97.6
-25.6
Pavlodar
4.9
54.1
45.9
533.7
28.2
N.
Kazakhstan
12.1
70.8
29.2
-828.7
-6.7
S.
Kazakhstan
12.2
67.8
32.2
199.1
6.9
Republic of Kazakhstan
7.0
This table
shows that agricultural production in Kazakhstan has low profitability
and out of5 oblasts that contribute over
10 percent of
agricultural outputonly three show
relatively good ratios of return on costs (Akmola – 9.9 percent, Almaty
- 11.2
percent and Kostanai - 11.8 percent).Also,
four oblasts recorded losses, while one reported a return on costs of
only 0.3
percent.Together these five
non-profitable oblasts accounted for 23.7 percent of agricultural
output in
2002 (6).
It is obvious
that one solution to
addressing rural poverty would be to increase agricultural production
and its
efficiency. Kazakhstan’s current levels of agricultural production are
already
sufficient for the domestic market. Therefore significantly
increased
agricultural production and efficiency on a significant scale would
have a
positive effect on the economy. The desired economic growth results
might be
achieved if Kazakhstan could increase its agricultural export capacity
by
increase of access to international markets. Improving such access
raises a
range of issues including improving transportation networks, achieving
international quality certification, and addressing agricultural
protectionism
of agricultural producers and potential import partners.
5.2. The Government
Policy and Strategy in Rural Area.
The Government of Kazakhstan has created a
range of programs and strategies, which aimed to reduce the gap between
standards of living in rural and urban areas. The creation of the
National
Rural Development Program for 2004-2010 is the main state program
within the
overall context of the Government’s strategy for recovery of a rural
area. The
objective of this program is establishment of proper conditions for
living to
rural residents on the basis of an optimized rural settlement. The key
element
of this National Rural Development Program is the classification of
Kazakhstan’s 7660 rural settlements into four economic potential of
development
based on 81 variables covering demographic, economic, social and
environmental
issues.
The categorization of rural settlements was made into the
three groups
such as high, medium and low scores and the results of classification
are as:
Economic
Potential Results
Economic
potential
No. of
Settlements *
Total
Population
High
1,062
1.6 million
Medium
5,664
5.3 million
Low
776
300,000
Neg.
environmental conditions.
22
10,000
* 136
settlements had been completely abandoned.
These results
underscore the challenges of
improving rural economic conditions (6).
The priority settlement for
future government
investment are those with high and medium potentialand investments in these settlements would be
made in such areas as agricultural production, processing industries,
expanding
market access andinbuilding
basic infrastructure network. Settlement
with low production capacity are to be evaluated to determine whether
it makes
more sense the settlements develop further or to resettle the
inhabitants,
while the rural residents of settlements with negative environmental
conditions
will be resettled to other settlement.
The total approved budget for 2004-2006 to
implement this program is 67.5 billion tenge from the central budget;
another
74.8 million tenge from the local budgets; and 34.8 billion tenge from
other
sources according to National Rural Development Program. Thus, the
total amount
of fund designated under this program accounts for 177.1 billion tenge
(the US
dollar equivalent is approximately 1.36 billion at the current rate KZT
130/
USD). No any cost and benefit analysis were made under this proposed
National
Rural Development Program.
The National Rural Development Program
identified that the majority of rural settlement are lacked with the
basic
infrastructure. According data provided by this program the percentage
of
settlements without water pipeline varies from 51.4 percent in Akmola
oblast up
to 88.6 percent in Pavlodar oblast. Regarding post office services
percentage
of settlement without stationary post office is in range from 35
percent in
Mangistau oblast and 76.6 percent in South Kazakhstan and mail
delivery in
78 percent of rural settlements takes place than 10 times per month.
The
majority of rural settlement does not have the paved roads and assess
to
communication services. Thus, rural areas are needed in providing the
basic
services and those would be provided by state funds for creating a
basic
infrastructure network.
In 2005 the Ministry of Agriculture has
recognized that 595 rural settlements have low potential of development
although originally the National Rural Development Program identified
approximately 800 rural settlements. The Government allocated 51.3
billion
tenge from central and local budgets in 2004. The funds were spent for
construction and repairing school, rural medical centres and facilities
of
potable water supply. Also, funds were spent for modernization of
communication
network, post offices and reconstruction of roads in rural areas. Thus,
the
implementation of the National Rural Development Project has started in
2004 as
it was originally intended by the Government. Despite the Government
spent
sufficient funds on this program it was noticed that no any improvement
and
modernization of rural infrastructure and other investments were made
in
Atbasar raion, particular in villages where the survey was conducted.
Most
likely it is explained by facts that these settlements have some basic
infrastructure and this Atbasar raion recognized as high potential of
development although the quality of available basic services to rural
residents
at the low level and numbers of these services are very limited. For
example,
no any of these surveyed villages has a fuel station and it was
possible to buy
fuel only in the raion centre or in one village, where the director of
farm is
kept the infrastructure from time of the Soviet Union and distance in
both
directions is about 100 kilometres.
The other major Government program in
agricultural sector is the State Agrofood Program of the Republic of
Kazakhstan
for 2003-2005. This program has three objectives: ensuring food
security,
establishing an efficient agribusiness system, and increasing the sale
of raw
and processed agricultural products domestically and internationally.
This
program currently is implemented by Ministry of Agriculture through its
ongoing
efforts to facilitate financing in the agricultural sector. According
to
information provided by the Agrofood Program allocations to agriculture
from
national budget represent 0.7 percent of GDP and this will reach at
least 1.8
percent of GDP starting in 2005 and will account for 15.9 USD in
support per
hectare of arable land.
The role of Ministry of Agriculture is to
reduce risk in financing producers and processing enterprises and its
approach
depends on the type of a borrower and it is determined as follows:
large
companies by means of reducing risk as appropriate; medium sized
companies by
means reducing risk and encouraging more banks to finance; individual
entrepreneurs and farmers by means of creation of credit union and
microfinance
mechanisms. Currently, the Ministry of Agriculture focuses on the large
and
medium sized companies and they are the main recipients of the state
support
programs.
In order to increase the use fertilizers and
elite seeds the Ministry of Agriculture established the programs for
subsidies
of purchases of seeds and fertilizers. The recipients of these programs
are
commercial and trading companies, providing the procurement of these
inputs to
agricultural producers. Thus, these programs allow to agricultural
producers
and farms to buy the fertilizers and seed on the subsidized prices from
these
companies.
Another
activity of Ministry is subsidies, directed to reducing risk of the
agricultural processor and the following program has been established: - subsidized interest
rate charges to processors by the banks, both for working capital and
for the
modernization of equipment; - subsidized lease
finance to the processing industry, provided Kazagrofinance.
Kazagrofinance, the state owned leasing
company was established by Ministry of Agriculture. In addition to
abovementioned lease program for processors this company provides the
lease of
agricultural machinery such combines and tractors to agricultural
producers.
Funding of Kazagrofinance is made from state budget and this allows to
company
keep the low interest rate in leasing agricultural and processing
enterprises,
which accounts for 7 percent per year. This factor makes Kazagrofinance
very
competitive on the lease market while other financial entities should
make own
funding at this rate and higher either domestically or internationally.
Also, Ministry of Agriculture introduced the
warehouse receipt program through the Receipt Insurance Fund, a
government
agency under Ministry’s responsibility, which insures grain receipts
for its
members. The activity of Receipt Insurance Fund is regulated by Law on
Grain
and the private insurance funds also might be established by current
legislation and operate in framework of this law.
The
Gosprodcorporatiya, a state owned business entity, which purchases
grain for
the Government’s reserves and provides price stability in the
market by
introducing purchase prices for grain, on which the grain could be
bought from
the agricultural producers. The Gosprodcorporatiya also provides
working
capital for purchase of input for sowing under guarantee of commercial
banks
and farmers in turn should sell its harvest to this state entity on
before
agreed price.
In order to increase the
production of
livestock the Ministry of Agriculture created the state company “Mal
Onimderi”,
which is intended to provide the price stability in the livestock
industry by
purchasing livestock as well as creating livestock brand and promoting
export.
Also, this company is to be providing assistance producers in
organizing the
further processing of meat and other livestock products and to help
those
companies to sell these products both on the internal and international
markets.
At the beginning of 2004 the Ministry of
Agriculture elaborated the Law on Mandatory Crop Insurance for Natural
Disaster
and this was adopted by Parliament in March of 2004. The Ministry of
Agriculture is going to give a priority in providing assistance through
state
programs to those farms and producer, who have already insured their
crops for
natural disasters. Thus, the agricultural producer and farmers have
incentive
to be insured by insurance company. In Atabasar rayon the farmers were
insured
by one insurance company and some farmers expressed the doubt that this
insurance company will have enough funds to cover all losses of
farmers.
Another doubtful point is whether this insurance company has a desire
to fulfil
their obligation under its insurance contract.
In addition to its efforts to reduce the risk
in agricultural finance, the Ministry of agriculture actively
encourages the
commercial banks to lend to the agricultural sectors through different
programs
such lending program of the World Bank, other donor organizations and
agencies.
The third category of borrowers, which are
individual entrepreneurs and small farmer are the category for which
state
microfinance program has started only in May 2005. This microfinance
program
intends to be large on amount of 5 billion tenge (approximately 36
million USD)
in its first year and to extend the credit on amount from 70 thousands
tenge (approximately
500 USD) up 140 thousands (approximately 1000 USD).
ADB regional project “ Rural Finance in Central
Asia“ in 2004 stated several potential design elements of this draft
microfinance program, which are causes for concern in the future
implementation
of this program. First, the rapid roll-out of the program indicates the
serious
underestimate of the necessary infrastructure and training required to
implement such microfinance program. As prove of it, currently the
representative of this program in the Atbasar raion is managed by a
person, who
is a civil servant of a raion executive body. Second point, the
objectives of
this proposed program are not clear, particularly the degree to which
potential
borrowers are essentially grantees versus viable borrowers, who simply
do not have
access to finance. Third, there is apparently the preference to
diminish
the rate, at which the rural sector loan will be made. This contradicts
to best
practice in international microfinance, which has shown, that
microfinance
borrowers should be able and willing to pay market rates of interest
and low
market rate threatens the long term sustainability of the microfinance
providers. All microfinance organizations in Kazakhstan charge the
market
interest rate, which allows them to be operating and profitable.
Finally, the
experience of NGO Microcredit, a Government owned MFI created in 1998
gave a
cautionary lesson. NGO Mircocredit’s loans are disbursed on the
recommendation
of the local Akim and council of elders in the rural area, thus credit
decisions were made on connection rather than business acumen.
Therefore, it is
expected that the repayment rate of this program was approximately 81
percent
on loan portfolio of approximately 9 million USD. This compares badly
with that
of the best donor-funded microfinance institutions in Kazakhstan.
Another strategy of Ministry of Agriculture in
microfinance mechanism development in a rural area is creation of the
Agricultural
Credit Corporation specifically to initiate the esatblishment of rural
credit
unions by providing equity and debt financing. In order to be
eligible
for ACC participation, a rural credit union must have a minimum of
twenty-one
members, each with a minimum contribution of approximately 700 USD (the
minimum
capital requirement is 3 million tenge, which is approximately 20
thousands
USD). The Agricultural Credit Corporation also provides equity
financing in
range of 39-59 percent in each credit union. As of 1 of January
2004 79
rural credit unions operated with ownership of the Agricultural Credit
Corporation and out of this 49 credit unions have received licenses of
National
Bank of Kazakhstan and are entitled to borrow from commercial banks.
The Agricultural
Credit Corporation intends to create a total of 90 rural credit unions
by 2005
and a total of 120 by 2006. It is supposed that the Agricultural Credit
Corporation will exit from the ownership of credit unions, although
there is no
stipulated time frame for doing it.
As the ADB regional project noted that a
positive
outcome of the Government’s rural credit union program is that it has a
demonstration effect and provides the actual experience in the
functioning of
credit unions. Nevertheless, this program has some deficiencies, which
are
follows: only well connected rural inhabitants are able to join to
these credit
unions; not only minimal capital contribution requirement is a
constraint for
many potential members, but the subsidized financing term inevitable
create
rent seeking incentive. According to the current Law on Credit Unions
(28,
March 2003) credit unions are not allowed to take a member deposit and
therefore the further growth of these entities are limited. Also, the
credit
union can not lend money outside of the credit union membership.
It is
evident that for an ordinary farmer the access to direct state
assistance is
quite complicated issue, because almost of those programs are directed
for
large agricultural enterprises and processor. Those ordinary farmers
might be
eligible to investment or short-term financing for under state programs
if they
could provide appropriate collateral such as new or non-obsolete
machinery,
real estate in urban area and high liquid assets. Also, the process of
allocating funds is not transparent at least in some programs. Thus,
the actual
implementations of these state supports program are so far from
providing state
assistance to small farmers.
5.3. Analysis of Crop Growing
Production.
As the northern region of Kazakhstan is
favourable for crop growing the almost all agricultural entities use
mainly
cereal farming system. It is explained by facts that grain is main
exportable
agricultural commodities while other products sell only on the internal
market.
A small number of private farms is involved in cattle breeding,
particular in
steppe areas under pasture farming system. Within cereal/pasture
farming system
the main commodities are cereals, meat products, dairy products, hides
and skin
and wool.
Currently the vast majority of cereal producing
enterprises is operating a low input. Therefore, this is low input
production
system. Seed, fertilisers, herbicides, and fuel/spare parts are the
principal
needs. The majority of farms purchase only fuel and spare parts while
large
agricultural enterprises purchase all above mentioned inputs. Although
the
purchased quantities are consistent with needed requirements and
the
amount of used fertilisers and herbicides are limited. It is explained
by the
climatic constraints of northern Kazakhstan and an average yield of 1.4
tones/ha is the most that could be expected with timely completion of
all
operations. This yield level remains marginal for sustainable cereal
production. The productivity levels could be significantly raised only
by use
of irrigation. The small amounts of additional water (about 200-250 mm)
with
use of higher levels of fertiliser and herbicide could provide yields
up to 4
tones/ha. Thus, depending upon the cost of providing supplemental water
such
cereal production system could be highly profitable. Without additional
water
the average yields in most area of northern Kazakhstan, are
unlikely to be
enough to meet the substantial cost of investing in modern equipment
(4). But
the investment cost for development of irrigation system would be
significant
burden for agricultural farms, which would not be covered for short
term
period. Thus, the prospect of many large farms, continuing the
historical
farming system of cereal production would be limited by abovementioned
reasons.
Another characteristic of farming
system in northern Kazakhstan is that the relatively extensive
cereal farming system requires only a small labour force, but
considerable
mechanization. The current farming system would be efficient if the
size of
farms is more than 3 thousands hectares by opinion of many farmers and
agrarian
experts. In time of Soviet
Union state and
collective farms used to have such squares of agricultural
lands under cereal production. The expenses in sowing and harvesting,
particular fuel would be less on large land plots than on small land
plots.The tractor or combiner will make
less turns
and will be able cover more area by one round.
In order to form a farm with size of 3
thousands hectares it requires 120 people assuming that average land
share is
25 hectares. Only 15 people would employed by farms initially and
eventually
10, because under this farming system one man per 200 hectares is
realistic
initial ratio gradually increasing to at least 300 hectares per
employees and the
rest of people would out of economic activity under agricultural
production. Thus
this is economic reality which requires the serious consideration
should be
given to assessing the needs and prospect of those who would not
employed by
farms.
In same farms the small number of workers
would be required by ancillary productions such as workers of social
infrastructure: canteen, workshops, public bath and etc. But such farms
are
more exceptional cases that the common cases not each large farm are
willing to
take extra financial burdens, particular when no any local authorities
force
them to take the responsibility for creating social facilities for
needs of
rural residents. The employment of all rural residents under
agricultural farms
is likely not possible and therefore the unemployed rural residents
have to be
engaged in other economic activity such as self-engagement or
entrepreneurial
activities.
Almost all small farms work independently
without any help from the state and they had to operate on a low input
system.
Small farms purchase only the seeds and fuel while they large farms
used to buy
fertilisers and herbicides in limited quantities. Only a few farms in
project
area conduct the preparatory work with land before sowing and other
works with
land and only one farm in the Atbasar raion conducts all work with
land,
specified by the technology of cereal production. This allows to this
farm to
have a good yield to compare with other farms although this farm has
low
quality land. Thus, the low yield in cereal production is revoked not
only by
low level of used input but it is caused by improperly work with land
before
sowing and after harvesting.
The inability of small farms to conduct all
needed work with land required by technology is explained by lack
of
financial and technical facilities. The main supplier of financial
resources is
Gosprodcorporatiya although some private entities also provide
financing
the farmers for seasonal works in some regions. These private entities
are more
flexible and propose to farmers more convenient terms for working
capital
financing. They accept the farms machinery as collateral although
commercial
banks these farms machinery are considered by banks as ineligible
assets for
taking it as security for farms financing, except newly bought
machinery.
A competition between state and private
entities provides small farmers with short term financing for planting
and
harvesting. It is supposedly that increase of competition would provide
more
appropriate terms and conditions for financing farmers. As example, the
price
for fuel is lower in Atbasar than in Astana or oblast centre although
this
raion centre is removed from both cities approximately on 240
kilometres
in both directions. It is explained that several supplier of fuel
operate in
this raion centre and some of them is from other regions. It is
explained that
Atabasar is main cereal production region among others and has
potentiality to
grow with developed infrastructures: rail way and road connection,
sufficient
numbers of elevators and other facilities for storage and processing of
cereals.
Thus, the farmers of this cereal production
area may survive without getting assistance from the state support
programs.
But those small farms are not competitive with large farms, because the
cost of
agricultural production is very high and overhead expenses per hectare
will be
high for them. The crop failure in last year revoked the losses of
small farms.
Hence, these farms became insolvent. The private business entities have
to
continue financing these farms in order to that these farmers
would be
able to repay these debts of previous years from the harvest of next
year. Such
behaviour is reasonable for private entities because they do not intend
to work
on land and they are only interested on purchase of cereals on
appropriate
price for them and thus they are not interested in bankruptcy of these
farms
although they can bring a suit to court for initiating the bankruptcy
of these
insolvent farmers.
The small farms agricultural production of
cereals is inefficient due to small size of land plot, lack of
machinery and
facilities for storage and keeping wheat in good conditions and high
cost of
financing. The machinery and storage service are demanded in cash, but
the
farmers prefer to pay in kind due to absence of cash. By paying in kind
the
farmers usually lose more than if they do in cash. The sustainability
of small
farms depends directly from level of yield and as they have to pay,
mainly in
kind for provided services to business entities and therefore farmers
have less
wheat for sales on the market. Thus high yield of cereals gives to the
small
farmers more profit on the cereal agricultural production and farmer’s
sustainability depends also from external factors, contributing to a
good yield
such as sufficient level of precipitation, rainfall, condition of soils
and
etc.
5.4.
Inconsistency of Legal and Institutional
Frameworks.
The process of decision-making
on land granting
is in the hand of local administration and the raion branch of the
Agency for
Land Resources Management is responsible only for land administration
and the
relevant branches of the Ministry of Agriculture stay apart from this
issue and
they are responsible mainly for procurement of farms with inputs under
state
programs although the amount of state funds and subsidies, which
reached to the
raion level are insignificant.
The decision-making process in area of land
relation is allowed to be made within three months by land legislation
and it
definitely slows the process of land granting. Kazakhstan has
clear
defined procedure for a state registry and compiling a land cadastre.
But this
system highly centralized and it creates inconvenience to applicants,
because
following decision on land grant the rural residents for getting land
use or
ownership rights have to apply different state agencies, which are
mainly
located in the oblast centre. And it is quite long distance for rural
residents
and it will be about 300 kilometres and more from some remote
villages.
Also, it will take time and money, but it is more crucial for
applicants is the
absence of public transportation network, which allows them to get to
this
oblast centre from place of their living and currently operating
public
transportation means are not enough to serve the rural residents in
delivery
them to the oblast centre. In this context it is not clear how the
rural
residents would be able to register their land use rights in state
agency
without having own transportation means.
Currently,
there are no
institutions and organizations, responsible for support of farms and
agricultural development. Only
the Republican Farms Association with
its
territorial branches involves in support of farms and small
agricultural
producers. The level of support to farms depends mainly from the
activity of
chairman and farms, who are the member of branches of Farm Association.
The
Farm Association and its territorial branches are public organization
and there
is no state involvement in statutory fund of these organizations. This
Farm
Association does not have any assess to state funds and international
credit,
because the Government implements its current state programs through
its
established legal entities in most cases fully owned by state. The same
procedure is applied to other programs related to agriculture, funding
of that
is made through borrowing from international financial institutions.
The
Government does not realize the potentiality of using the branches of
the
Republican Farm Association in implementation of state programs
directed to
support and development of rural areas.
The Ministry of Agriculture and the Agency for
Land
Resources Management and others such as Gosprodcorporatiya and the
Receipt
Insurance Fund are responsible for certain part of a state policy
program and
they have clearly determined functions and there is no conflict between
those
state bodies and entities for having more power and influence in
governance of
rural sector of Kazakhstan. Only the Agency for Land Resources
Management and
Ministry of Agriculture has a presence in the raion centre of rural
area. The
operational activity in these branches is governed by republican or
regional
offices and these branches have limitation in management and making
decision,
particular raion branch of Agency for Land Resources Management does
not
empowered in making decision of land granting.
The Government does not foresee the future a
role of non-governmental organizations such as Farm Association and
other
micro-finance organizations, currently operating by the support of
donors and
external borrowing from commercial banks. These micro-finance
organizations
operate mainly in the southern part of Republic of Kazakhstan and some
of these
organizations work successfully in rural areas. One of successful
operating
micro-finance institutions, extending credit in rural areas is Fund for Support of Entrepreneurs. The predecessor of
this Fund was
Winrock International, who established program to support farmers in
Almaty and
West Kazakhstan Kazakhstan in 1998. Then Winrock International made
some technical
assistance and financial contribution in establishment of new Farm
Credit Funds
in other four regions of Kazakhstan and all these established funds
work
successfully now in their region.
All currently
operating micro-finance institutions have started their operations from
technical assistance and support, provided by international donors such
as the
Mercy Corporation, ACDI VOCA and others. This provided the
micro-finance institutions
with sustainability and most of them currently operate financially
independently now. It seems that the officials diverges the experience
of these
micro finance entities in establishment of credit delivery mechanism to
farms
and agricultural producers, because the Government never expressed any
interest
to work with these organizations on programs aimed for development of
rural
area.
Thus, the
Government does not want to employ the existing institutions of
non-governmental organizations and has limited the presence of
government
agencies only through establishment of two basic institutions branches
in each
raion of (MoA, AfLRM), which were mentioned early. As prove of
the
Government reluctance might be ignorance of the branches of Farm
Association,
which might serve as agent in promoting state policy in rural area
through
state programs. The use of branches of Farm Association will provide
with more
efficient implementation of state programs, because the staff of these
organizations knows the farms, their capacity and local conditions for
farming.
Currently,
some branches of Farm Association work with farmers and small farmers
understand that it is very important for them to unit around these farm
associations. In the Atbasar raion local branch of Farm Association has
about
70 farmers (it is less than half of all registered farms, not each
registered
farms currently operate now) as a member of this organization. These
farmers
pay to this Farm Association an annual membership fee and staff of Farm
Association provides the farmers with inputs on the conditions, which
suitable
and acceptable to farmers. Moreover, these farmers are eligible to
state
programs by various reasons such as lack of capital, absence of
acceptable
collateral and small size of production and etc. For example, Gosprodcorporatiya provides the
farms with short term financing under guarantee of commercial banks,
who in
turn request the liquid collateral from farmers for securing liability
of
farmers under provided Bank's guarantee. And not each farmer has liquid
collateral such as a flat or house in cities, new machinery and market
demanded
assets. The farms from this region, which were able to get financing
under
state programs used to have the flat or house in Astana. The majority
farms do
not have such collateral and they are not accepted by commercial banks
for
providing credit or guarantee.
In order to overcome these obstacles the Farm
Association of Atbasar raion found one buyer of grain and this
trading company provides short term financing on the same scheme as
Gosprodcorporatiya
does, except that this trading company accepts as a collateral the
obsolete
machinery of farms and other assets of farmers, which is not so
attractive and
liquid by consideration of commercial banks. The conditions of contract
between
farms and this trading company are more suitable to farmer,
particularly on the
price of grain, because it influences on farm profitability. Thus, the
Farm
Association helps to farmers in their current farming activities and
provides
the farmers with appropriate scheme of financing.
The Land Code and with other normative acts
provide the whole legal framework governing land relation, but this
land
legislation does not contribute to further development of land market
in
extend, which initially was intended by legislators. The Land Code
itself does
not respond to the needs of farms, who are main stakeholders in land
relations
and the introduction of the Land Code was revoked by political will of
Kazakh
authorities and desire of business people, involved in grain business.
The main task the Land Code is to provide the
defence of rights of land owners and land share owners and the latter
does not
have any workable mechanism for defence their rights although the
Land Code
foreseen three alternatives to these rural residents. The majority of
rural
residents, who intended to organize own farm have already taken this
possibility for starting own farming. The remained part of rural
residents has
only option to put their lands shares to a statutory fund of
partnerships and
other legal entities. It means that there is problem lack of
system in
organizing the process of management with land shares. It is likely
that no any
owners of business entities desire to have several hundred or
thousand
participants in their business and such number of share holders or
participants
in the partnership or members in production cooperative will create
complication in making some strategy decisions, where the approval of
all
owners is needed in accordance with business legislation.
Such cases might be applying for getting credit
from the commercial banks, sales of a company shares, mergers and etc.
Getting
approval from several hundred participants will slows the process of
management
and making decision by company managers. The owners together with
managers of
such company will try to find the solution to avoid such complicated
way of
getting approval and most likely they will try to reduce number of
owners by
purchase of shares from these new participants of company. Thus, the
right of
land share owners could not be defended fully by the current land
legislation,
because the land share in the statutory fund of these legal entities
will be
governed by civil legislation and it means the land share could be
tradable
commodities and value of these shares will be determined by agreement
of two parts of
this
deal.
It should note that land share owners do not
have sufficient level of knowledge of such transactions legal
procedure
and situation has worsened by the absence of clear procedure of land
share
evaluation. Besides, to the proposed approach of land share appraisal,
based on
receiving dividends by land share owners at one fifth the net profit of
business,
the Research Centre suggested that determination of the value of land
shares
must be made by conclusion of auditors or by agreement of parts. The
appraisal
of land shares by agreement of parts does not work properly, because
the rural
residents do not have any options in some villages.
The approach in appraisal of land
shares, which was recommended by the Research Centre, has not been used
by all agricultural
entities and in some villages the indication for determining land share
value
was an amount of previous rent payments for lease of land share and it
is
evident in case of re-registration of “Elena” Ltd, “Hrushevka” Ltd.
Some agricultural
entities followed to official recommendation (“Panfilofskoe” Ltd,
“Orlan” Ltd).
The re-registration of rest companies, mainly newly established
supposed to be
made on equitable basis and only “Karazhar” Ltd was registered with
equal
shares of each participant in the statutory fund of partnership.
Also, this proposed recommendation is not
difficult for implementation, but it would not provide the same
amount of
appraised value of land share in different enterprises and therefore
there is
no economic logic, when the value of same amount of land and same
quality would
be appraised differently within one raion. The amount of these
agricultural
entities statutory fund varies from 90th.tenge (670 USD) to 8.5 million
tenge
(64 thousands USD) and they have in possession various squares of
agricultural
lands. Thus, proposed recommendation seems to be incorrect, because
there is no
economic logic between that land use rights should be 20 -25 percent of
statutory fund and the required amount of statutory fund for
partnership is
considerable less that cost of land use rights. Also, the cost of land
use
rights or private land ownership and cadastre (evaluated by state)
value is
much higher than the value of appraised land share in agricultural
entities and
it is shown in the table below (last column). No any methodology for
determining the cost of land shares has been suggested by the relevant
bodies,
including non-governmental organizations and agricultural scientists.
The following data on the re-registration of
agricultural entities were obtained during conducting field research in
Atbasar
raion and it is presented below.
Name of agricultural entities
Total
agricultural land, ha
including
arable land, ha
Quality
score of land, bonitet
Share
of one new participant in statutory fund, %
Share
of founders in statutory fund, %
Appraised
value of one share, tenge
Amount
of agricultural land/arable landin one
land share, ha
Elena Ltd
6
496
4
060
37,3
0,14
80
12
000
32/20
Hrushevka Ltd
591
580
29,9
1,54
55,34
14
000
32/20
Karazhar2004Ltd
2
212
1
036
34
N/A
3,571
23
852
79/37
Orlan 2030 Ltd
1
474
1
005
42,2
0,15
90,1
3
712,5
25/15
Abilai Khan –Sadybek Ltd
480
176
29,9
2,5
60
10
000
30/11
Zolotaya Niva Ltd
1
470
980
32
1
51
18
000
30/20
Panfilovskoe Ltd
No
date
No
date
No
date
0,0918
80
83,19
45/31
Continuation
Number
of participants
Value
of founder properties, intenge
Cadastre
value of land, in tenge
Statutory
fund of entity,in tenge
Total
amount of contribution of new participants, in tenge
Relation
of new participants contribution to statutory fund, %
Relation
of land cadastre value to statutory fund, times
141
6
867 000
130
698 900
8
571 000
1
692 000
0,20
15
29
500
000
16
671 690
906
000
406
000
0,45
18
28
N/A
16
791 983
667
856
667
856
1,00
25
67
2
229 975
48
438 588
2
475 000
248
738
0,10
20
16
240
000
1
602 202
400
000
160
000
0,40
4
49
918
000
12
833 200
1
800 000
882
000
0,49
7
218
No
date
46
775 537
90
625
18
135
0,20
516
The data presented above on
agricultural
entities in Atbasar raion, re-registered according to requirement of
the Land
Code proves that approach, based on Recommendations of the Research
Centre is
not correct, because the various amount of statutory fund of business
entities
and number of participants with their virtual amount of land share make
impossible to use such approach by diversion of land share
value more than
hundred times. It is nonsense when the same amount of land appraised
has such range. Thus, the necessity to introduce a fair system of
appraisal of
land shares is urgently needed.
It is obvious, that the
Government
concentrated
mainly on the economic efficiency of agricultural production in the
land reform
and they transformed the social support of rural residents from area of
land
legislation to the area of agro-industrial complex. But the
effectiveness of
such decision has hampered by presence of unsolved issues until
present time.
The main unsolved issues derived from legal arrangement of state
governance and
policy of the Government aimed for achieving effectiveness and in many
cases
through ignorance of socially vulnerable people group interest and social
issues, which used to be solved in other civilized countries. The land
legislation has several issues: - absence ofsystem of modern electronic cadastre of real estate
in the rural area; - absence of real market
assessment of land,
thatwill influence on the possibility
to realize
the land use rights and land shares as contribution to statutory fund ofbusiness
entities, pledge and sales of these land use rights, including
ownership rights; - changes of quality land
indicator without
adequate records in land cadastre; - no transparency inaccount of land and in procedure of making
decision on landmanagement, including land granting; - low level of income
considerable part of
rural residents and 30,9percent of theruralpopulation have income less than the
minimum
subsistence income; - absence of land
infrastructure and control
over lands; - inability of majority rural
residents to be
involved in land circulations; - low level of awareness of
rural residents as
a owner of land shares and land userights
about their rights and liabilities in relation to given
them land shares or
landuse rights.
All those unsolved issues are crucial to the
further development of rural areas and creation of competitive
agricultural
production. Some of these issues, which are key technical issues of
land
legislation, ought to be solved urgently in order to create workable
legal
framework of land legislation. The remained issues might be solved only
by
introducing relevant state policy in regard to rural sector of economy
of Kazakhstan and changing the current practices
of state and local administration. The unsolved issues such as absence
of
transparency in account of land and in procedure of making decision on
land
management, including granting land granting and absence of land
infrastructure
and control over lands are derived from the established procedure of
state
administration, conducted by the civil servants. Authorities of Kazakhstan both republican and local are much
concerned with decision making rather with process of further
administration.
They more stressed on the resources allocation procedures, because they
empowered to make such decision without any control from public and
society and
any legally established clear defined criterion a for ranking received
applications and grounds for refusal or approval. It is relevant to
other sensitive
issues of pubic management and not only for land legislation.
Previously, it
was mentioned that land legislation delegated so much power to a local
administration and it is provided by the established state governance
practices
of the Republic of Kazakhstan.
It should be noted that currently the basic
legislative acts itself of Republic of Kazakhstan has been elaborated
on
satisfactory level. Some legal acts in public management are based on
concept,
which does not respond to market economy and are very close to the
previous
system of a command economy in some sensitive issues as example,
administrative
licensing, trading. But this Land Code meets the international
standards to some
extends
and does not contain any evident drawbacks. Moreover the Kazakh
legislative
system precisely delineate the responsibility and functions of each
state body
and there is no overlap of state bodies functions in the
administration
both on republican and local levels, particlar in land relations.
Therefore it is very difficult to
find
some issue in the land legislation, such overlap could be met. But it
is
evident that so much concentration of power in hand of the Government,
presented by oblast and raion administration. Therefore, the other
relevant state bodies have not empowered to content any decision of
local
administration and they implement only technical work on administrative
decision of local authorities. It is relevant to administration of
local
authorities in area of land relations.
It is very difficult to criticize
the introduced Land Code, because this legal act contains some
provisions,
which meet the general requirement of land legislation and respond to
technical
aspects of this issue. But this Land Code has been elaborated by
legislators
without taking into account the current status of rural residents,
existing facilities
in rural area and ability to rural residents and stakeholders to be
involved in
the process of land circulation as it was intended originally by
officials.
Also, this land legislation would not diminish the abuse from local
administration against of land users and rural residents, wishing to be
involved in farming, because there is no precise rule, on which
particularly
land granting decision would be assessed. Thus, the legal framework on
land
relation need to be improved to some level, which would allow to rural
residents, who are capable for farming to be a land tenant.
6.Needed
Supporting Strategies in Land Reform
The attempt to introduce
supporting strategy in the land reform is justified not only by
necessity
of the
agricultural development, but also low level of living conditions of
people in
rural areas. The rural focus can also explained that rural territory
account
for 97, 2 percent of Kazakhstan’s territory and share of agricultural
production in GDP of Kazakhstan diminished from 34 percent in 1990 to
8,7
percent in 2001 and to compare with 1995 it declined from 12.3 percent to 7.9 percent
in 2002. This share of agricultural
production remains very low among other GDP
of the CentralAsiaRepublics (Tajikistan- 25
percent, Turkmenistan -29
percent, Uzbekistan -37
percent of their country GDP). 43.7 percent
of population
of Kazakhstan,
living in the rural areas produce less than 8 percent of GDP. This means almost
half population
stay apart of economic production and rural residents do not make any
contribution in the development of country.
Among of the non-Baltic former Soviet Republics
the Government of Kazakhstan has an impressive overall track of
records. As
examples of that might the implementation of the most successful
banking sector
reform, reduction of inflation to fewer than 10 percent per annum by
1998,
following the hyperinflation of the early 1990s, creation of a National
Oil
Fund to guard against Dutch disease by conservation of some oil
earnings for
future generation, implementation of a three pillar pension program,
privatization and attraction of foreign investment in key industries
such as
oil, non-ferrous metallurgy and etc. These conducted reforms together
with
substantial growth of prices for oil and metals allowed to the
Government of
Kazakhstan to provide the economic stability and substantial growth of
GDP with
increase of production and export, mainly crude oils and metals.
On the contrary the
agriculture of Kazakhstan encountered
with serious problems, which caused the abovementioned fall of
agricultural
production. These problems are a significant number of inefficient
operating
small farms, the price disparity, when prices on industrial inputs
exceed the
prices of agricultural products, lack of working capital, inability of
farmers
to provide themselves with machinery, seeds and fertilisers and other
chemicals
and etc. Although rural sector began to recover since 1999 the overall
situation is still complicated. There is decrease of birth rate
although it was
traditionally a high rate of birth in rural areas. The rate of
mortality is
still high, including deaf of children and mothers. The continuous
emigration
of rural residents to urban area calls for improvement of demographic
situation,
which in turn depends from social and economic environment of rural
area.The decrease of state expenses for
needs of
health and irrationally conducted “optimization” of medical
establishments in rural area have deteriorated the health status of
rural residents.
Despite on presence of the announced state
programs for development of
rural area and agricultural sector by officials there are no
substantial
improvements in the living conditions of rural residents. Hence, the
implementation of this strategy does not lead to social and economic
development of rural
areas and
consequently to the growth of rural residents welfare. Also, it was
stated in
UNDP Human Development 2002 “Report Rural Development in Kazakhstan:
Challenges
and Prospects” that the living standard of every individual in rural
areas is
unsustainable
from social, economic and environmental points of view. “Nowadays no
any doubts
the facts that analysing the economy, social sector or administrative
reforms
from human development perspective allows us to better assess the
effect and
ultimate goals of given changes”. Any reforms remote from people
may
bring only temporary benefits and it would be unwise to ignore the
human
aspects. Also, the sustainable development would not be achieved
without
securing the living conditions for the whole population of rural areas
(11).
Consequently, in order to stimulate
people-oriented
strategy for economic growth and social development it is necessary to
introduce the strategy aimed to improve significantly the living
standards of
rural residents in all aspects and to strengthen the state
administration and
other state
agencies and organizations, involved in agricultural production, which
will
lead to increase rate of employment of rural residents with adequate
remuneration for work engagement.
The concept of supporting strategy in the land
reform with involvement of relevant state bodies at the central level
and local
level should be considered by the Government the Republic of
Kazakhstan. This
supporting strategy is to be implemented by the Ministry of Agriculture
under
guidance of the Government of the Republic of Kazakhstan. The
involvement the
Agency for Land Resources Management is necessary in the implementation
of land
reform in land relations. The formulation and implementation of
supporting
strategy in the land reform could be supported by technical assistance
from
donors or contracting consulting companies.
This strategy in the Land reform will be
integrated into a single program and this program would fund as
integrated
package rather isolated elements. Each region might have an integrated
regional
program, but these regional programs should coincide with strategic
direction
of a national program. The program might be implemented through state
financing
and international borrowing, if it is needed to have funding from
donors.
The proposed supporting strategy in the Land
reform
would include the following components such as development of farming
entities,
strengthening the raion branches of the Agencies for Land Resources
Management
and assistance to the rural residents in getting land tenure and
the
legal components comprising proposal, which might be introduced into
the Land
code and land legislation.
6.1.Further Development of Farming Entities.
The supporting strategy in the land reform
comprises the strategic direction of farm development in rural
areas,
which was neglected by officials of Kazakhstan. It was a few attempts
from
Asian Development Bank since 1997 to introduce farm development
strategy
through the pilot project in some selected oblasts of the Republic of
Kazakhstan.
It was intended by consultants of ADB to provide a support to farms in
the
framework of this proposed development project. The project preparatory
work
had been done by the end of 1997 and development project had been
submitted by the Bank to the officials of Kazakhstan.
Finally,
the Government of Republic of Kazakhstan rejected this project and then
they
started to prepare own state support programs, where farmers were not
considered as targeted beneficiaries. The recipients of these state
support
programs are mainly trading companies and large agricultural farms.
Thus, the
small farmers, which appeared after privatization of state and
collective
enterprises, had to operate without any state supports.
The previous period of reforms has shown that
only small part of newly appeared farms were able to develop in proper
manner
and the key of their success was ability of them to get financing
from the banks due to having liquid collateral. Also, these farms tried
to
increase
the scale of production by taking additional land in possession under
land use
rights or by rent of and shares and it provided these farms to operate
on large scale production.
The increase of sowing areas contributed to financial viability of
these farms
and provided them with sufficient earning. Then these farms have made
investments for acquisition of new machinery and other necessary
agricultural
equipments through borrowing from commercial bank and partly through
own
earnings.
The reforms proved that without any active
support from state and other donors the villages is bound to be poor in
market
economy conditions. A key to many current rural problems - such as
unemployment, poverty and poor infrastructure- is the development of
agriculture, which might be part of a multi-faceted state rural policy.
The
agricultural development of rural area might be implemented by
providing
support to farms through state bodies and other non-governmental
organizations,
related to agricultural sector.
The support to farms might be implemented
through the branches of the Farm Association, because some
branches currently provide support to small farmers in their
current
operations in some rural areas. The current activities of
branches of
Farm Association in collaboration with farmers might be reinforced
through
technical and financial support from state and international donors.
Also, this
support to Farm Associations might be supplemented on the institutional
level
and the branches of Farm Association establish a Farm Support
Service
Centre.
The role of
the proposed FSSC would be essentially co-ordination and advisory
services. The
structure of this FSSC at the local level is designed to implement the
support
to farmers and other small business of rural area. The staff of
FSSC would
be able to provide advisory to farms in any farm activities, especially
in farm
management. Broadly, the main aim of the FSSC would be help to
formulate
farm management or restructuring solutions, acceptable to those
involved in agricultural production, to
ensure that people are fully aware about their options and to support
their
decisions with sound analysis which highlighted the economic
consequences. In
detail, the tasks, which supposed to be performed by FSSC are the
following
issues: -providing the farmers
with appropriate farm decisions by choosing the rightproportion
of capital, land, labour
and crops;
-assisting to farmers in getting short term
financing, agricultural
inputs on appropriate prices and
conditions of repayment
including
organizing bulkpurchase of agricultural
inputs
and sales of agricultural products in largequantities and rent of
machinery services at
appropriate prices to farmers;
-getting acquaintances of farmers with advanced production
technologies and new productive
machineries
and agricultural equipments;
-providing awareness of rural
residents with the
procedure in applying for land granting under land use rights or private
ownership for
farming and with rights and
liabilities of land
users/owners under current land legislations;
-serving a liaison in extending state support programs and
other
donors programs to farms, who
needed and
eligible for such
programs;
-checking matching farming methods
with the most
appropriate climatic zonesand
greater concentration
of production;
-assistance in revival of best
farming practices and
dissemination of successfultechnologies
among other
farmers;
-organizing co-operation among farms and integration of
farms and
processingfactories, trade
companies and commercial
banks. In order to
provide these services the proposed FSSC should have qualified staff,
which
might be trained by specialized training programs under state budget
financing. Also, these FSSC under the Farm Association should
be
recognized by the state bodies, responsible for development of
agricultural
sector i.e. the Ministry of Agriculture. The recognition of FSSC should
be
confirmed by signing bilateral agreement between those parts,
allowing to the Farm
Association with its branches to act as an agent in agricultural
development of
rural area. Also, the Farm Association should be involved as an agent
in state
and donor support programs.
The role of
policy and legislation is to provide with an efficient framework, but
at the
same time, this framework must have an operational capacity. In other
words, any
legislation including land legislation with adequate introduced the
market
economy attributes such as private land ownership would not work
properly if the
business environment under which farms operate does not correspond to
principle
of market economies. Thus development of farming entities will became
increasingly dependent upon the capacity to apply market economy
principles to
develop: - landregistration
system; - land
valuation and land management procedures, including land granting; - transformation
of farming entities into profitable enterprises; - restructuring
and/or rehabilitation of agro-enterprises; - assess to
rural credit and rural credit delivery mechanism; - commodity
marketing infrastructure; - modern
information and data processing networks; - effective
and efficient administrative systems, especially public accounting,
taxation and
judiciaries. The
operational capacity would be provided by putting these systems,
networks,
procedures and methods together. Without succeeding it the operational
capacity
would be the major obstacle for completing the process of agricultural
reforms.
Despite Kazakhstan is still transition phase the Kazakhstan economy would be to provide the Government with the
required
budgetary resources to strengthen operational capacity
. The branches
of Farm Association would contribute to development of operational
capacity at
least in transformation of farming entities into profitable enterprise
and
restructuring of agro-enterprises, in assess to rural credits and
creation marketing infrastructure. The rest issues would be solved
only by the
Government in co-ordination with other relevant state bodies.
The main
task
of Farm Association would be assistance to farms in getting sustainable
operations
and currently branches of Farm Association implement this task, because
the
activity of such organizations aimed to get as more as possible farms
in their
organizations as members.The staff of
branches of Farm Association
comprises
small number of worker and in many cases there are chairman, accountant
and
might be one supporting specialist. The actual work of these branches
is
conducted by chairman, who is experienced agricultural specialist with
a broad
experience in agricultural production and good knowledge of region and
specific
issues of agriculture. But, the existing branches with such limited
number of
workers would not able to render an advisory and consultancy service in
dimension of as it is intended by proposed farm assistance in order to
develop
sustainable farms in rural areas. Therefore, there is a necessity to
have any
additional specialists in order to provide with wide range of services
to farmers
and a number of these consultants will depends on number of farms, but
each FSSC
should have farm at least a farm management specialist, economist-
financier
and technical specialists such as agronomist, land and marketing
specialist. The
needs in other specialist such as livestock and processing specialist,
and
others would be determined by regional branches of Ministry of
Agriculture by
request of branches of the Farm Association.
The Farm
Support Service Centre would be established in each raion where branch
of the
Farm Association operate and this
diversified network of Farm
Support Service Centre would be subsidized by
a state
in order to make these units operational. It is desirable if the
subsidies
from the state will be applied for period of three years and more and
then
these FSSCs would be able to operate without financial aids. Until now farmer are reluctant to pay for
consulting services. It is proved by experience of the Agricultural Post
Privatization Assistance Project under World Bank, which was
implemented in
1998-2001 as a pilot project in Akmola and Astana oblasts. In framework
of this
project the Rural Consulting Centres were established in Almaty and
Astana
cities under financial support of project. In late stage of project
implementation it was intended that these centre would operate without
any
financial support and the rendering consulting services would be made
on paid
basis. Finally, these centres have
terminated their activities due to absence of demand on paid
services from agricultural producers and processors. Other technical
assistance
projects tried to create consulting services in rural areas and they
failed,
because these established consulting centre or firms could not operate
without
financial aids from donors. The reason of failure is based on absence
the
demand for paid consulting services due to mentality of farmers and
lack of
money. Some branches of Farm Association as in case of Atbasar raion
found the
good
solution to earn money by introducing only fee for membership. Rendering services on paid
basis would
be applicable in the future when farmers would have a sufficient earning and understand the
importance of consulting services particular in farm management. Thus, the
financial support would be applied while these FSSCs would become
financially
viable and would be able to sustain in their business operations.
Then, the source of income of FSSCs would be fees for consulting
services. Also, the successful branches of Farm
Association usually are headed by a person, who is respected by farmers
and has
capacity to attract farmers for co-operation in purchase of inputs and
getting
financing from commercial traders. Thus, the activity of branches of
Farm
Association would contribute to co-operation of small farmer not only
in
purchase of inputs and getting seasonal financing, but also they would
help to
farmer to unit into a group of farms for joint work in farming such as
rent of
machinery, sales of agricultural commodities products in large
quantities, in
storage and processing and etc. Finally, the farmers would come to idea
to
organize some public organization such as co-operatives or associations
of
agricultural producers with involvement farmers and processors.
The core issue of proposed strategy for
agricultural development is the creation of viable farms, which would
be able
to grow and enlarge the scale of production. This enlargement of some
farms
would create employment, increase of tax collection from rural areas,
growth of
salary of rural workers, which might be revoked by needs in qualified
workers.
Also, the increase of farms income will allow them to use the advanced
technology and increase of use fertilizers and chemicals in order to
get a high
yields. Thus, the assistance to farmer would be made with goal to help
some of
them, at least to grow to the level of efficient production and some of
them
would be able became large scale farming entity. It does not mean that
less
capable farmer would stay without any help under this strategy and all
farms
would have the equal access to support from FSSC. But the farmer who
would be
able to use the effective way of farm management likely would be
successful.
Also, it requires the flexibility and capacity to learn to best
practices on
farming and farm management. Thus, Farm Support Service Centre should
serve not
only as a centre, which helps to farmer in their farming activities and
it should
be
a centre, where the consultancies on the best farming and farm
management
practices would be available and latest informationon
the market prices as well. These assistances to farmers would
contribute to further
development of
farming entities, especially small farms in rural Kazakhstan.
6.2. Assistance to
Rural Residents in Getting
Land Tenure for Farming. Although the Land Code foresees
the granting
land to rural residents into private ownership or under land use rights
the procedure
of land allocation for farming by current land legislation is
supplemented with
necessary submittal some documents besides the basic documents
abovementioned in
the Chapter 3.2. These documents comprise
the brief program of supposed farming, proof of experience in
agricultural
production or presence of relevant education or passing special
training in farming, copy
of taxpayer and address of a head of peasant farm.
Not all applicants, wishing to be a farmer
would be able to prepare the brief program for supposed farming
without
help of
external persons such as consultants or agricultural specialists. The
number of
agricultural specialists, who is able to prepare such documents, is
very limited
while consultants are hardly available in the raion centre and this
consulting
assistance to farms might be provided only in the oblast centre.
The more serious obstacle in getting land
tenure for farming is requirement for having agricultural
experience or presence of special education or training in agricultural
production.
Almost
all people, older than 35 years old have some proves of involvement in
agricultural production due to records in the Work book, which was a
required
document in time of the Soviet Union, where any work engagements were
recorded
with indication the position and name of employer. But in regards to
people
under 35 year old it is not clear how they could provide proves of
their
engagement in agricultural production, because after failure of the
Soviet
system it was not required to make records in the Work book and from
this
period
many farms were incurred to bankruptcy or were closed by various
reasons and
only a small number of farms could survive after period of collapse of
agriculture, which was in 1993-1998 and they still operate in rural
areas. These
farms would be able to provide only a certificate of employment and
consequently only part of rural residents, who had a chance to work for
such
farms, would be eligible to get land tenure. Regarding young people,
who never been involved in agricultural production, the land
legislation does not
provide
any visible solutions. One option exists to such young people, if they
never
had a land share, is to get a relevant study or special training in
farming.
These opportunities are hardly visible, because such training could be
provided only
in oblast cities on paid basis and this amount of paying together with
cost of
living are huge amount of money, which ordinary rural residents never
had
before. Thus, the land legislation allows to rural residents to have
land
tenure for organising farm, but some established requirement makes it
is
impossible to rural residents, particular to young people.
This problem might be solved through providing
special training in farming and farming management of proposed trainees
at the
expense of state budget. This special training would be provided with AgriculturalUniversity and
almost all agricultural regions have an AgriculturalUniversity and in
case of absence of such University such courses might be established in
other
Universities or Institutes, area of specialisation of which is close to
agriculture, for example, Institute for Water Irrigation in Dzambul
city. In
case of absence of an appropriate high educational establishment this
special
training might be established within an agricultural college.
The rural residents, who expressed desire to be
a farmer should submit the application to the local administration,
which in
turn have
to inform the regional administration about number of participant for
special
training in farming. When collection of application will be completed
the
relevant department of regional administration would make decision on
organising a special training in farming and farm management either
in the
certain raions or in the regional centre.This
decision should depend on number of proposed
trainees.Most likely, these courses would
be better to
organize in the regional centre, if a number of trainees in any raion
would be not
enough to
conduct such training.
The selected educational establishments for
providing such special training in farming should have farm business
faculty
with relevant teaching staff and training facilities.The recent establishment of farm business
faculty in the AgriculturalUniversity in Astana might serve as example of
a proposed educational establishment, supposed to be involved in
training in farming and farm management. The regional state budget
would
contract such educational establishment or at least reimburse the
expenses of
these educational establishments in conducting special training to
future
farmers.The variant of contracting
would be appropriate, because in this case the high educational
establishments
would be have the certain liabilities in providing training for
farmers, which
might be established in the contract. Such training might be extended
to
applicants of all ages and to current farmers, who need in special
training in farming.The
significance of organising such training to rural residents would be
difficult
to estimate and such initiative would give to rural residents some hope
in
establishment of their own farms and therefore they would be able to
improve
their living conditions by involvement in agricultural productions. As
the current
land legislation requires from applicants to have at least some
relevant
education or training and it is more reasonable to provide the
applicants with
necessary knowledge and qualification than to try to cancel this
provision in
the land legislation. Also, the cancellation of such requirement would
be
difficult and there is no common sense to give land tenure to people,
who
would not
have a basic knowledge in farming and farm management.
6.3. Strengthening of
Raion Branches of Agency forLand Resources Management.
The raion braches of the Agency for Land
Resources Management are not empowered in the process of decision
making in
land granting although they are involved in the current process of land
administration according to land legislation. In accordance with land
legislation the regional branches of the Agency for Land Resources
Management conduct
allwork in land granting while the
raion branchesare responsible for
current land management such as monitoring the appropriate use of land
by landusers
and the quality of land and providing data for land cadastre and
regional
branches. Also, the raion branches were responsible for implementation
some
provisions, related to land share issues and cancellation of sub-leases
and
providing helps to farming entities and farmers with implementation
their
rights and liabilities under the current land legislation.
As a raion branch of the Agency for Land
Resources Management is the responsible agency for implementation state
policy
in land relations it is reasonable to delegate some more empowerment in
the current
process of land granting. As raion branches conduct work with landusers
and
they are aware better about the situation in land issues in their raion
than
the regional branch of ALRM and therefore it would reasonable to give
more
empowerment to raion branches, particular in the process of land
granting to
rural residents. A regional branch of ALRM is involved in process of
land
granting only in technical issues mainly in regards of technical
possibility to
provide the applicants with the requested land plot in the certain
area.
Therefore, as a regional branch of ALRM makes only technical decisions
and all
other issues, affecting to making a land granting decision are
considered by
the local administration. As this decision is made by discretion of
land
committee, headed by akim of raion it would reasonable to authorise the
raion
branch to conduct all work, related to technical issues of the land
granting
process.
The authorisation of raion branches of ALRM to
conduct work, relevant to land granting process such as search of
a suitable land
plot, contract preparation, acceptances of payments would accelerate
the
process of consideration of application for land granting as there is
no need
to send the application to oblast centre. Therefore the farmers would
be
benefited, because they can save money and time. The preparation
project design
and physical identification of land plot also might be implemented by
the raion
branch of specialised state agency. All those involved technical
agencies are represented
in raion centres including state agency for registration of real estate
and
deals and therefore the decision on land granting might be implemented
on raion
level.
The objection against providing the raion
branches
with such authorisation might be that these raion branches do not have
enough
capacity to implement such work on proper manner. It is correct in some
extend,
but the raion branches of ALRMemploy
the specialist with college and university degree andsome of them are qualified specialists with
relevant education in area of land relations. Therefore, the staff of
raion
branches must be capable for further training due their professional
occupation
and educational background for more responsible work.
The proposed training is to be done in
framework of proposed institutional strengthening of raion branches of
ALRM.
This institutional strengthening in addition to proposed training might
include
the increase a number of specialists and technical reinforcement of
raion
branches with additional equipments and facilities,changes of
regulating
provisions in regards of delegation of more responsibility to raion
branches in
land management. The latter issue might be settled by the Agency for
Land
Resources Management itself by changing the certain provisions,
regulating the
function of structural levels of this Agency and in some other points,
where it is
need by consent of the Government. Also, the training of staff of raion
branches might be implemented on the current expenses of the ALRM or on
additional financing from the state budget. As concerning
the
increase of number specialists and technical reinforcement by providing
additional equipments it is necessary to develop the budget for
institutional
reinforcement of these raion branches of ALRM.
The
precise amount of
additional state financing would be determined after conducting
revision of
existing equipments and facilities, which are in use by these
branches
and on the basis finding the needed amount of equipment and other
facilities
would be proposed to state financing in framework of proposed program
for
strengthening raion branches of ALRM. The same approach might be used
in getting
the state financing for additional staff of raion branches. These
issues might
be solved with close co-operation with the Agency for Land Resources
Management. Without getting the preliminary agreement from the
Government it
is likely to introduce some serious changes in current
delineation of empowerment
between raion and regional levels of the ALRM., because such changes
would
weaken the centralised system of governance by opinion of the
authorities.
Thus, delegation more responsibility to structural units at the raion
level is
rather a more political issue than the subject of technical
implementation.
6.4. Proposal for Introducing Change in Land
Legislation
The introduced Land Code comprises the all
necessary attributes of land relations, which contributes to proper
land
management under market conditions and regulates the interactions
between main participants
of land market and also defends the land form against deterioration of
land
conditions by introducing sanctions and mechanism for withdrawal of a
land tenure
from them, who unconscientiously use agricultural lands.
In whole, the Land Code itself
advances the
market reforms by introducing private ownership for land of
agricultural use with
keeping land use rights. Although the Land Code provides the legal
framework
for an efficient land reform the outcomes of such policy is hardly
visible in
nearest futures. As it was noticed by land specialists the private land
market
is not formed in all regions of Kazakhstan, except on irrigation lands in the
southern regions. There is no any case of acquisition of agricultural
land into
private ownership in Atbasar region as in other cereal production area
of the
northern and central part of Kazakhstan, zones of risky land
cultivation
although the land legislation provides to purchase the land on
discounted price
up to 75 percent of cadastre value and on delayed payments for 10
years. Thus,
the development of private land market is highly doubtful in the
nearest
future. Other reasons, affecting on this issue are high established
prices for
agricultural land and low incomes of rural residents.
In May 2003, the deputes of the Parliament
introduced
in the first draft a provision regarding allocation of land to rural
residents
on unpaid basis, but later the Government had withdrawn this norm from
the Land
Code and they explained that introducing such norm would create the
danger for
140 thousands operating agricultural enterprises. Nowadays, when
private
ownership for land of agricultural use became paid it is unlikely to be
possible
to come back to idea of granting land to rural residents for free.
In order to
stimulate
the creation of private land market on rainfed agricultural lands it is
necessary to reduce the cost of agricultural land significantly,
because on
such prices no any rural resident and agricultural entities would be
able to
buy the agricultural land into private ownership. For example, the cost
of
arable land in Akmola oblast is 49.4 thousands tenge per 1 hectare
(approximately 370 USD) and while the cost of the irrigated land
in this
area is 71.9 thousands tenge (approximately 537 USD). As regards of
southern
region the costs of irrigated land are in range of 74.5 and 87.8
thousands
tenge (approximately 556 and 655 USD). Thus, the difference between
non-irrigated and irrigated land in prices for land acquisition is not
significant. But in term risk of possible crop failure due weather
conditions
this comparison is not to favour of possible owners of non-irrigated
land,
because risk of crop failure under irrigated land is insignificant to
compare
with non-irrigated land. If the officials are eager in
development of
private land market on non-irrigated land they have to reduce the cost
of land
otherwise agricultural entities and farmer would continue to keep the
land use
rights for agricultural lands. It might be implemented by introducing
the
change in the Resolution of the Government # 890 dated 2 of September
2003,
which serves as implementing regulation for the Land Code.
But more important issue to rural residents is
to
not lose their shares in the agricultural enterprises, which they
acquired
by
contributing their land shares to statutory fund of these enterprises.
Also, it
is important to them to get, at least the same benefit as they used get
by rent
of land shares before. In accordance to obligatory contributing the
land
shares into statutory funds of business entities the owner of shares
became as
participants of these partnerships, members of production co-operatives
or
peasant farms and shareholder of joint stock companies. These new
owners of
these business entities have the right to sell their shares to
any
buyers, including to this entity itself. If the new participants of
such
business entities would sell their shares they will get insignificant
benefits,
because the average assessed value of 1 land share (it comprises 32
hectare of agricultural land including arable
land of 20
hectares) in presented data on
farms of Atbasar raion approximately
about 90 USD in while the highest value is 178 USD
and the
lowest is 0.7 USD.
Therefore, if the agricultural entities would
intend to release from these new participant they can purchase the
business
shares of new participants at low price, because the assessed value of
land
share is small. Thus, there is urgent need to introduce some provision,
forbidding the sales of these shares and stating that shares of such
participant of agricultural entities must be regulated only by land
legislation. The general legislative framework on partnership of the
Kazakh
Civil Code contains provision, stating the sales of partnership share
is
allowed if the current legislation does not make any restriction. The
same restriction might be introduced on shares of joint stock company
and contribution of production co-operative. Definitely, introducing
such provision,
restricting
rights of participant of agricultural entities would defend the right
of these
people from loosing by themselves their ownership rights in such
entities.
Another
crucial issue for new participants of agricultural entities is the
absence any
provision, determining the ways and procedure of the appraisal of land
shares. As
it was mentioned before the Research Centre under the Presidential
Administration
proposed alternatively that evaluation of contributed land shares into
statutory fund of business entities must be made by agreement of parts
or
conclusion of auditors. As matter of fact, no any operating
agricultural
entities used the auditors in determining value of land share and all
deals
were made under absence of any alternative options, except in some
villages
there were only two or three options, but their proposed values of land
share
were at the same level without any large differences.In relation of newly established entities there
were possibilities to appraise land shares on equitable basis.
The data on re-registration of
agricultural entities in Atbasar raion has proved impossibility to
bind the
appraised value of land share with statutory fund of agricultural
entities. The assessed value of land
share
should be so low otherwise the share of new participants would take a
significant
share of statutory fund. Therefore the significant part of business
entities profit
must be paid to new participants and it would not make a sense to
founders of
such entities to keep these new participants as owner.
Also,
it is impossible
to take the cadastre value of agricultural land as a base for appraisal
of land
share, because the various numbers of participants and amount of
statutory fund
make it impossible. It is explained by fact that there is no any
proportional
dependence between land cadastre value and statutory fund of
agricultural
entities. And it is proved in early presented data on agricultural
enterprises
of Atbasar raion, where relation of amount of land cadastre value under
possession by these entities to statutory fund amount varies from 4
times up to
516 times. Therefore, such divergence of this parameter makes
impossible to use
the cadastre value of land as base for appraisal of land shares,
contributed to
the statutory fund of agricultural entities.
One possible solution for finding appropriate
approach
and procedure for determination of appraised value of land share is to
calculate
possible profit, which might provide a land share to agricultural
entities.
This income would be defined through development of budget of certain
type of
crop production on the basis previous years data of agricultural
production such
as yields, cost and sales prices. This
approach might be used by state agricultural research institute or
other
consulting institutions by request of the Ministry of Agriculture.
In 2003, the Republican State Enterprise
“Scientific
research institute of economy of agro industrial complex and
development of
rural territories” elaborated methodological recommendation on
organisational
economic models of agricultural entities in the Republic of Kazakhstan.
This
recommendation comprises the different farm models of the various
specialization
of agricultural production for all regions of Kazakhstan. In other
words, specialists
of this institute have elaborated the budget of main type of
agricultural
production for all regions of Kazakhstan, including crop growing.
The recommendation contains the farm model
budget of cereal production in northern region and this proposed farm
model is
calculated for 840 hectares of agricultural land. This farm model
budget has
all economic and financial data including yields, revenue, cost and
profit. The
latter might be used for appraisal of land share, which was contributed
to a
statutory fund of agricultural entities. The profit of model farm,
involved in
cereal production in the northern region is 2.91 million tenge (21.7
thousands
USD) according to estimates of above mentioned institute in this
recommendation and hence a model farm would get 3.46 thousands tenge
(26 USD)
from 1 hectare of agricultural land. This amount of possible profit
from 1
hectare might serve as base for establishment of appraised value of
land share,
contributed to a statutory fund of agricultural farm.
The rural resident by contributing land share in
amount of 30 hectares of agricultural land would provide the
agricultural farm with
additional profit on amount of 104 thousands tenge (775 USD). Thus,
this amount
would be taken as an appraised value of land shares, contributed to
statutory
fund of agricultural farm. This contributed land share could not be
considered as tangible asset, because this land share is an
artificial arrangement,
invented by the Government during conducting privatization of state
farms and
therefore applying the techniques of appraisal of any assets would not
be
correct. Thus, the procedure of appraisal of land
share
must be solved by administrative decision of the Government, because
this
issue is subject of the Government concerns and they have to provide
the
rural
residents with some benefit for their contributed land shares.
Another important issue is payment of earning
to new participant of agricultural entities. The appropriate way of
earning
payment would be paying at the fixed rate on appraised value of land
shares something
like paying on privileged shares. This fix rate on earning paying would
be equal
to estimated net profit ratio of relevant model farm. In case of
Atbasar raion
the model farm has revenue from sales of agricultural commodities on
amount of
10.67 million tenge (79.6 thousands USD) and cost of production is 7.76
million
tenge (57.9 thousands USD) and profit amounts 2.91 million tenge (21.7
thousands USD). Therefore, the net profit on sales of this model
farm is 27,2 percent and this figure might be established as fixed rate
for
payment dividends to new participants of their land share to this
agricultural
entities. The farm must pay to each participant of its entity
fixed
payment on amount of 28.3 thousands tenge
(211 USD)
annually.
Another option might be introduced by the
Government by taking the amount of possible sales of agricultural
products
from one
hectare and it would be considered as assessed value of land share.
This
amount of
revenue must be multiplied on coefficient of net profit sales, which is
27.2
percent and finally the received profit should be divided on three and
it means
that one third earning would be paid to participants of these entities
and two
third of earning would remain in hand of agricultural farm owners. In this
case the
farm would pay to each participant a fixed payment on amount of 41.1 thousands tenge (307 USD). The
allocation of earning
between these parts might be made on equal base, but in this case farm
owners would
think about releasing from these participants.
The second option is more preferable to new
participants, because they can get more earning from agricultural
entities. But
the
agricultural entities are reluctant to pay a high price for land share,
because
they paid before rent payment in range 10-12 thousands tenge (75-90
USD) and
then they might come to another alternative opportunity to rent the
agricultural land
from state directly. In the second options it would more difficult to
force the
farms to agree with making payment at fixed rat, because theywould insist on some failures, which may
occur to weather conditions.Definitely,
the farms would not agree with the first option, but paying would be
less
than on
the second option. Both options would provide rural residents with
increase in
getting payments from farms in 2.4- 2.8 times in the first option and
3.4-4.1 times
in the second option to compare with previously received lease
payments.
The idea to make payment at
fixed rate from
assessed value of contributed shares would defend the rural residents
from
cheating them by agricultural entities by conducting double accounting
and avoiding
additional cost for conducting auditing, which is very expensive for
agricultural entities. Moreover, auditing is compulsory only for
financial
organizations including bank, insurance company and joint stock
companies and
rural residents are not aware about how to check the plausibility of
farm
accounting. Also, agricultural entities have some legally established
privileges such as transference of losses during three years and other
legally
established tax reporting techniques, which allow them to work
unprofitable for
long period without any punishment from tax inspectorate. These farms
would
face only to one danger, when tax people could prove that farm
accounting
was conducted incorrectly and it less likely in rural areas due to
inability of
raion tax officers to conduct such auditing on proper manner. Also,
these
agricultural entities have significant powers and influence for local
administration, because they are main tax payers in the raion and they
would
find some agreement in such issues. One of these above mentioned
approaches must be
introduced by the Government resolution by using the calculation of
authorised
research institute such as above-mentioned state research institute or
consulting entities. Also, the Resolution of the Government must
comprise some
provision, providing annual payment so-called dividend for contributed
land
shares at fixed rate to rural residents in cash. Also, the Government
has to
force the agricultural entities to make dividends payments to new
participants by
introducing liabilities for avoiding making such payments otherwise
these rural
residents would not get anything from agricultural entities.
7.Analysis of Policy Scenarios and Implication for
Rural Area.
The land
reform,
introduced by the Government, approach of donors in assistance of
agrarian
reform and proposed alternative land reform might be analysed by
comparing
policy scenarios and its implication for rural areas. This analysis is
needed
in order to predict the consequences of various policies in agrarian
reform and
assess the possible impact for rural residents and farm entities. Also,
this
analysis of policy scenarios is supposed to foresee the future
development of
rural area and predict all possible negative and positive changes to
which
rural areas and rural residents might be incurred.
In order to conduct such analysis it is
necessary to employ the data on farms of Atbasar raion and
other information, related to
land
relation, social economic status of rural residents and all these data
were collected during conducting field work. Second,
this analysis would be conducted in context of certain established
social and
economic goals, which should be achieved by introducing the land
reform.
Third, it
is supposed to determine efficiency of probable scenarios of land
reform for
development economy of rural areas and how and in what extent these
possible
scenarios would solve the social and economic problems in rural areas.
Forth,
this analysis would consider consistent and realistic perspective on
the role
of government in land reform. Finally, the possible undesirable social
outcomes
would be identified in order to diminish the negative impact to rural
areas from
the government interventions by means of introducing regulative acts,
relevant to land relations.
Thus,
the
analysis of policy scenarios would be an assessment of current land
reform and proposed
alternative agrarian reforms, comprising land relations. This
assessment would
take into account the feasibility of successful implementation of these
agrarian
reforms. These assessments are supposed to contain some results and
facts to which some policy scenario in the agrarian reform might lead
and
these
outcomes would serve as a basis for making a conclusion on the policy
scenarios with
describing consequences, which would affect to rural residents and
development
of rural areas.
7.1. Introduced Land Reform by Government.
The Land
reform, introduced by the Government is
intended to develop the private land market in the rural area by the
adoption
of
private ownership for land of agricultural use, which would contribute
to
increase of agricultural production and facilitate assess of farmers to
the credit
and other type of alternative financing. Despite the Government of
Kazakhstan
has established the legal framework for acquiring land plot into
private
ownership nowadays no any transaction of a purchase of
agricultural land
into private ownership from state has occurred in Atbasar region. This
means that
the development of private land market in the rural area is under doubt
particular in the region
of rainfed agricultural lands while it promises to be organized on the
southern
region, where the irrigated lands are always attractive for farming.
The land reform with its transitional
provisions has obliged the owners of a land share to make a decision
with their
land shares and the majority of the rural residents have contributed
their land
shares to a statutory fund of agricultural entities. These contributed
land
shares were assessed at the low price and the founders of these
entities have a
significant share in these entities. The share of founders varies
in the
range of 51 -90 percent of a total business statutory fund. The newly
established agricultural entities have assessed the contributed land
shares
higher in comparison with the assessed value of a land share in the
existed agricultural entities. Hence, a share of founders in
the existed entities is in range of 80-90 percent while a share in the
newly
established agricultural entities is in range of 51-60 percent. But the
lowest
appraised value of contributed land shares would give an opportunity to
the
founders of these entities to repurchase the shares of these new
participants
at low costs for them.
As
it was noticed before
that a significant number of agricultural entities participants hamper
the
process of management decisions, where the approval of all entities
participants is needed and it could be a reason to the main founders of
these
entities for releasing from such number of participants. Another reason
for
releasing from these new participants might be appeared after a few
years of
successful farming when the founders would be reluctant to share with
their
profits with the new participants and, in turn the latter would expect
to get adequate
dividends on their shares, because they would know that the
agricultural
entities have good profit. Thus, this business relation would work only
on a
period, when farms would not be able to get good profit and in this
case the
founders of these agricultural entities would have some justification
for not
paying the adequate dividends for contributed land shares to new
participants
of these entities for their contributed land shares. The crucial
factor, which
would undermine this fragile relation between these new participants
and
founder, is legally established compulsion on the founders of these
entities to
accept these owners of land shares as a participant of their
agricultural
entities. It contradicts to the main principle of organizing any
business that
the establishment of business entities must be done by group of people
on a
voluntary basis. As matter of fact, the participants of any business
entities
have some close relation to each other and this does not exist between
the
founders and new participants in these agricultural entities.
The agricultural entities had to follow to this
direction and finally they would release from the excessive number of
new
participants. The proposed techniques would be based on the general
provisions
of the civil legislation, which allow the sales, exchange, beneath and
other deals
with shares of any business. After several years of paying a small
amount of dividends or
not paying any dividends the new participants of these agricultural
entities would
have sell their business shares to the business entities itself in
order to
get
something. There are so many possibilities legally to reduce the profit
to minimal level such as sales of agricultural commodities to the
affiliated
companies at low price or increase the cost of production
by purchase of
inputs, machineries
and services from the affiliated company at high price. These
possibilities are visible to implementation for the large agricultural
companies, because as a rule the founders of such companies have some
involvement in other business,
related
to agricultural production such as a participation in the ownership of
elevators,
trading companies, providing the procurement of main agricultural
inputs.
Thus, the rural residents would lose their
share of a participation in these agricultural entities after sales of
these
shares to the agricultural entities and they would not have any means
for
living, as they previously had such as a rent payment for lease of land
shares,
mainly in kind. These rent payments provided the rural residents with
feed for
animals such as cows, sheep, horses and etc. The absence of such
meaningful
benefit would jeopardise the rural residents in loosing their
livestock,
because these rent payments provided the rural residents with feed for
animals.
Under such circumstances the rural residents would have less
potentiality to be
covered with their needs in the food, clothes, coal and other expenses
for
proper living. The financial status of such rural residents would be
worsened
and it is likely that the employment in the rural area would be on the
same
level as it is now. Hence, it is not clear how the rural residents
would be
able to survive under such conditions. Most likely, this proposed
scenario
would contribute to the growth of poverty among rural residents while
the
Government of Kazakhstan reports the increase of Kazakhstan GDP up 2000
USD per
capita in 2005, which would be provided mainly by sales of crude oils
and other
raw materials such non-ferrous metals, coal and other minerals.
This
proposed scenario is based on the previously mentioned data on farms,
which were collected in Atbasar raion and reluctance of the large
agricultural
farms
in acceptance of these new participants was proved by fact that
these
agricultural entities completed
legal
procedures for
re-registration of their business entities just before deadline as it was prescribed by
the land
legislation. Also, it was some cases when these agricultural entities
refused
to take land shares from some rural residents due to personal non
acceptance of
these people and sometimes by the reason of diminishing the number of
participants
in their business entities.
By introducing the land reform the
Government has not been succeeded in establishing the efficient system
in agricultural sectors, which will lead to the growth of agricultural
production and
people welfare in the rural area. The
cancellation
of land shares lease has created the inconvenience to
agricultural
farms in
2004, because they were forced by the land legislation to take the new
participants
instead of continuing the rent of land shares from rural residents.
Now
these large
agricultural farms became a business entity with bulky management due
to a
significant number of participants, who do not make any significant
influence for
operation of farms, but their approvals on some management decision are
needed
by the current business legislation. Hence, this requirement would not
contribute to establishing the efficient system of agricultural
production,
because
it slows the process of farm management. Also, the growth of rural
resident’s welfare is
under high doubts, because if a farm reports the losses nobody would
have the right to
claim for getting dividends according the general rule of a business
law. If a large farm would report the
losses or low
level of profitability the budget of raion would have inconsiderable
tax collection from these farms. Thus, this
possible scenario
would not solve the social and economic problems in rural areas.
As matter
of fact, the role of the Government in the land reform is limited only
by
monitoring of activity of land users through the raion branches of the
Agency
for Land Resources Management although the Government announced the
number of
farm supported programs. Presently, the Government does not have any
network on
the raion level for providing assess of small farmers to these program.
And the
recipients of these programs are only the large farms and allocation of
funds
under these programs is made at the republican and regional
levels.
Although the Government reports on allocation of the significant amount
of
budget resources in the agricultural sector and actually these
funds were
allocated mainly among large farms. Therefore, the Government does not
undertake any measures to support small agricultural producers and
entrepreneurial initiatives in rural areas.
It is
evident that the undesirable social outcome would be further worsening
of the financial welfare
and social status of rural residents and this would be negative impact
to rural
areas from this introduced land reform. Besides, these rural residents
would be unemployed
group of
people without any earning and financial support from the state such as
social
aid because of losing the lease
payments for land share rent. Under
such circumstances, which were created by the state agrarian policy
it is unlikely that the Government would not be
able to
provide these rural residents with any possibility of employments and
other
means of getting money for their proper living and increase of their
living
standards.
7.2. Approach
of Donors in Agrarian Reforms.
The proposed approach to rural
development has been proposed in the
National Report
on Human Development 2002 “Rural Development in Kazakhstan: Challenges
and
Prospects”. This strategy comprises integrated implementation of the
following
three strategies: - strategy of agricultural
development; - strategy of infrastructure
development and
social development policy; - strategy to integrate efforts
of the state
and local communities in the process of rural revival.
The UNDP specialists recognize the importance
of land reform completion and emphasize the necessity of state
support
of individual households and development of social policy in rural
areas (11). But
actually these strategies are implemented separately by the various
international
financial institutions such as the World Bank, the Asian Development
Bank
with involvement
in the agricultural and infrastructure development strategies.
Currently the World Bank implements some
projects, which are supposed to contribute to the agricultural
development
such as the Second
Agricultural
Post-Privatization Project and Agriculture Competitiveness Project. A
few projects
are under analysis of the World Bank consultants and these projects are
relevant
to development of some sectors of agricultural production such as
livestock sector,
fisheries. On the contrary, the Asian Development Bank implements some
projects
aimed to create the rural infrastructure such as the Rural Area
Development project and
the Water Supply and Sanitation project while other donors such as
USAID and EU Delegation, implement mainly advisory technical assistance
projects.
All these projects appeared by the request of
the
Government of Kazakhstan, because any proposed development and
investment
projects need the approval of the officials of Kazakhstan before
starting
its implementation.
As these international financial institutions lend money to the
Government of
Kazakhstan the implementation of these projects is conducted only by
the
authorized
agencies of the Government and these project interventions are incurred
to some
changes and influence from the Government. Therefore, these development
projects are
the part of the Government strategy in rural areas.
It is known fact that the Government does not
take any concern about the status of the majority of rural residents,
who
are not
employed or involved in entrepreneurial activities. As matter of fact,
the
Government with its agricultural development strategy intends to
support some
large agricultural companies by providing them with access to
cheap borrowing. Other components of development strategy such as
access to international
market and strengthening the industrial competitiveness by means of
enhancing
quality of
agricultural commodities, introducing new technologies are under
projection.
As regards of the Agricultural Post Privatization project only the half
of
recipients of
loan out of 119 borrowers were farms although the total disbursed
amount of fund was more
13
million USD. Also, this program intended to a create rural advisory
centre, but
none of these created rural advisory centre in oblast centre works now.
Most
likely,
this forthcoming Second Agricultural Post privatization project would
be
successful in achieving established goals, but these
projects would not contribute to increase the number of sustainable
small agricultural producers
and the growth of entrepreneurial
initiatives in rural areas.
As regards of ADB activities the current
infrastructure
development project aimed to create proper living conditions in rural
areas by providing the rural residents with clean drinking water
in some
villages of the northern
and central regions of Kazakhstan. The Rural Area Development
project intends to support the National
Rural
Development Program for 2004-2010 and therefore the funds under this
project
are supposed to spend for building a rural infrastructure.
As these all proposals of donors are considered
by the Government the development
projects have to coincide with the policy and strategy of the
Government.
Therefore,
the interventions of donors in the form of development projects have
not be differed
significantly from the policy of the Government and nobody from the
Kazakh officials have expressed
any concern about providing the support to small agricultural producers
and
the social
policy development in rural areas. The positive impact from these
development
projects would inconsiderable and these projects would embrace only
viable farms
and business in rural areas. Small farmers and unemployed rural
residents would
stay out of scope these donors. Thus, the probable scenario is that
these
attempts of donors would not affect significantly on the financial welfare and social status of these
groups of people.
7.3. Proposed Land Reform with Supporting
Strategies.
The proposed land reform with supporting
strategies intends to cover some deficiencies of the current land
reform and
this also would mitigate the negative impact from conducted agrarian
reforms in
the last years. This strategy intends to facilitate access to land
tenure, to
provide the support to small farmers and to propose some legislative
proposals
in land relations.
The proposals to the current land legislation
intend to provide the rural residents with some dividend on their
contributed
land shares and to prevent the rural residents from losing their share
in
business entities. The introduction of paying dividends at fixed rate
from the
amount of contributed shares would provide the rural residents with
some
income. Also, the adoption of the unified procedure for appraisal of
land
shares would help to make a fairer appraisal of contributed land shares
to a
statutory fund of business entities. These proposed changes would
defend the
rural residents and provide them with stable income. Therefore, this
would
provide payable demand for services and goods. Thus, these legislative
proposals
in land relation would contribute to the growth of rural resident’s
purchasing
power. This would create the business environment for entrepreneurial
initiatives;
increase the number of self-employed people. Thus, the further
development of
small business in rural areas would provide the rural residents with
employment
opportunities.
The proposed delegation of more
empowerments to
the raion braches of the Agency for Land Resources Management and
establishment
of the Farm Support Service Centre on the basis of existed braches of
the Farm
Association together with providing special training to rural residents
in
farming would be supplementary efforts from the state in the creation
of
business environment
under which any person, wishing to be involved in farming, can start
farm
operation. The rural residents would have option to start farming or to
be
involved in entrepreneurial activities in addition to opportunity of
seeking
employment in the farm or to be involved in the public services. This
is very
important for rural residents of workable age particular to young
people,
because
they can provide a family with additional income, which will provide
more
savings in family budget.
The key issue of this proposed strategy is that
the current land reform ought to be supplemented through the state
support. The
proposed Farm Support Service Centre would a agent in providing this
support. Besides,
the getting access to state support programs the farmer would be able
to unit
for achieving some beneficial offers from the supplier of inputs and
service
providers for agricultural production. The further development of
farms
would depend on the ability of farmers to use the efficient methods of
farm
management and advanced production technologies, which would match to
appropriate climatic zones. The efficient transference of these farm
practices
and new technologies would be possible only among people, who work
closely and
therefore they have some good relations with each other.
The further growth of these farms would provide
them with sustainable operation and therefore these farms would
diversify their
farming activities and increase their scales of production and some
workers of
non-viable farms would be employed by these sustainable farms. Thus,
the
co-operation of farms for joint work would help
to solve
some problems, which might appear in farming activities and FSSC might
help them on this issue.These FSSC also will
help to processing
factories, financial establishments and trading companies to get a
business
link with farms as the Atbasar Farm Association does in its current
work. Thus,
the proposed integration between agricultural production and processing
factories, trade companies and banks would be visible under activities
of
proposed FSSC.
The introduction
of this proposed strategy would facilitate access of small farmers to
the state
programs without creation of any additional network in rural areas.Hence, the recipients of state and donors
programs
might be small farmers and the state support to small agricultural
producers would
be provided by these proposed FSSC, which should be established as a
public fund.
This public fund is a non profit organization by the Kazakh civil
legislation,
which means that all earned profit would be used only for established
goals and
objectives of this fund and therefore these funds are not keen in
getting high
profits.
The
proposed land reform suggests that the further development of farm
entities
would be implemented under competitive environment without any
protection of
any farms or any interference in the current activities of viable farms
from
the state bodies and local authorities. These FSSC are supposed to be
public
fund and the chairman of these Farm Association and FSSC would
accountable in
front of the state bodies only on actual implementation and use of
state
support programs funds. Thus, the best way in the development of farms
is to
give empowerment to public organizations, because they have to earn
money and
they are interested to make unfair performance on these programs. In
case
of latter the local authorities would be eager to get the power
for
implementation these state programs, because the administrative
control
over farms would reinforced by presence of financial means directly in
the
hands of local administration or indirectly through affiliated legal
entities.
7.4. Conclusion on
Analysis of Policy
Scenarios.
It is
evident that undesirable social outcome from the introduced land reform
is further
worsening financial welfare and declining the social status of rural
residents. This proposed outcome would
be mitigated by introducing the alternative strategies of land reform.
The
current land reform would not benefit the rural residents by the
following
reasons, which were mentioned early and one of most harmful provision
for them
is cancellation of sub-lease of land shares and land plot, therefore
expiring
validity of land shares, if the owners would not able to manage before
1 of
January 2005. The powerful political party” Asar”, which has some
influence to the
Kazakh officials, would not be able to cancel these provisions by
collecting
needed number of signatures for cancellation of these provisions. This
proposal
was blocked by the head of agrarian committee in the Parliament of the Republic of Kazakhstan, who is the largest owner of
agricultural land in the cereal producing areas. It is not possible
also by
another reason that the key issue of this land reform is the conversion
of land
shares in the way, proposed by the land legislation. This would
cause
negative impact to rural areas, because if agricultural entities do not
pay
dividends for their contributed land shares and the rural residents
would
remain without any earning and financial support from the state.
The
approach of donors
through some proposed development project would not make significant
improvement on the welfare and status of rural residents,
because these programs
are the part of current policy of the Government in regards of rural
areas. The
agricultural and rural infrastructure developments are implemented by
these
donors in ways, which are suitable for the Government. It is known fact
that
the state authorities desire to establish the efficient agricultural
production
and they ignore the needs of ordinary rural residents.
Although
the Government declares its desire to fight against poverty the current
practise of the Kazakh officials is so far from these declared
objectives and
the Kazakh officials, including local administration are not able to
provide
with additional employment in rural areas. If the rural residents do
not have
any earning any constructed faculties and services in rural areas would
be not
demanded by them and therefore these established infrastructures
would be
unused.
The
alternative land reform with supporting strategy would help to solve
problems
in rural areas in some extent, because the strategy aimed to help to
the small
farmers and unemployed rural residents. In the situation when the
created state
policy of the Government in regards of rural areas, particular in
agricultural
development does not consider the small farmer and ordinary rural
resident as a
subject of state support programs and only large farms get all these
subsidies
from the state budget the importance of such land reform is very high.
The land
reform with supporting strategies would give some hopes and
possibilities to
the rural residents to improve their living conditions through
involvement in
farming or employment business and the proposed changes in
the land
legislation with other proposed institutional proposals and providing
adequate
training for farming would help to create the employment in rural
areas
and hence, the rural residents would be able to earn money for covering
basic
needs in food, clothes and needed services. Thus, the proposed land
reform
would have some advantages against the current land reform, because the
Government and donors approaches do not give incentive and support to
entrepreneurial
initiatives in rural areas and the Government uses the same mechanism
of
implementation of agrarian reforms that unsuccessfully was used by
them in the last
years since failure of the Soviet Union.
8.Summary of Main Conclusions and Policy
Recommendations.
The introduced Land Code with some
provisions, relating to cancelling the lease of land shares would bring
the
rural residents to new changes of their living conditions. The research
showed
that likely these changes would have a negative impact, because the
rural residents
besides the weather conditions and market prices on agricultural
commodities would
depend from desire of farms owner in getting some benefits from
their
contributed land shares. As the rural residents do not have enough the
financial resources it would not clear how they could survive under
absence of
any financial means.
The intention
of this
research project is to investigate the current status of the poor part
of rural
residents, who are not employed on permanent base in farms or public
services
and are not farmers. The
overwhelming majority of
rural residents are such people. The project area was taken deliberately
in order to embrace the less adoptable rural residents to
market environment such as the rural residents of villages in the
northern
regions, who were involved previously in an ordinary work in large
state farms
and hence, they do not have working capacity for farming and
propensities to
entrepreneurship due to historical traditions and prevailing mentality
of these
people.
The
research showed that the established legal framework in land relations
does not
allow the rural residents to get a land plot for farming although the
number of
people, who expressed desire to start farm operation is insignificant.
It is
might explained partly that these people think that they would not able
work
properly in farming and they fear to take risks in a farming adventure.
But the
main obstacles for them are their mentality and they think that
somebody have
to take care about improvement of their financial status. Other
obstacles are
absence of any of financial means, including banking financing and
necessary
machinery for farming. The latter might be provided by specialized
machinery
service centres
although the
conditions of this machinery service centre is predatory and prices for
it
reaches up to 30 % of crop harvests. This possibility has been worsened
by the
complicated procedure for getting land tenure, because the all relevant
state
bodies are located in the oblast centre, except a raion local
administration.
The undeveloped public transportation infrastructures with remote
location of
oblast centre incur the potential applicants to serious difficulties in
reaching the state bodies and to considerable expenses, including
transportation cost.
The
invented procedure of land shares conversion into a share of business
entity is
not supported with relevant regulative acts, which are necessary
for the
proper implementation of transaction, required by the land legislation.
The
main deficiencies are absence the economically reasonable methodology
for an
appraisal of the land shares, which were contributed into a statutory
fund of
the business entities. Following to the recommendation of the Research
Centre
under the Presidential Administration lead to some nonsense when the
contributed land share costs less than I USD and this recommendation
does not
provide with a fair appraisal of the contributed land shares. Thus,
necessity
for elaborating a fair procedure of contributed land share appraisal is
needed,
because these land shares might be repurchased by the business
entity
itself or the rural residents might get a small amount of earning for
their
contributed land shares.
Another crucial point was identified by the
research that the small
farmers are not eligible for any state support programs and instead of
support
the development of small farmers all a substantial amount of the state
funds at
subsidised rate were allocated among the sustainable large farms, which
are
competitive on the market without these subsidies from the state. The
small
farmers are supported only by the local branches of Farm Association,
because
they are members of these associations. Nobody take cares regarding
encountered
problems in front of small farmers in their farming.
The proposed policy in the land reform has been
elaborated in order to
solve abovementioned problems, because these are crucial for proper
implementation of the land reform. The progress of land reform depends
from the
proper established legal framework and the procedures for land granting
to
applicants
and actual conditions, that the rural residents find themselves in. Any
established legal regime would not provide good results without having
workable
environment, which comprises a status of land users and rural
residents, an adequate infrastructure for business activities and
visibility of
the proposed
land reform concept. The latter it is very important, because the
legislators
could propose some effective solutions, but in reality these provisions
are not
workable due
to presence of external factors, which affect on actual implementation
of these
proposed solutions.
The proposed solutions have been identified
during conducting the
research and these solutions are derived from the data and other
information,
which were collected through the surveys, interview, official data and
other
source of information. Also, the proposal of research does not require
substantial institutional changes such as creation of a new state
agency or
significant changes of the concept of the land reform. This is an
attempt to
propose some changes, which would be visible if the Government decided
to apply
some “political will” to change the situation in rural areas. It
requires only
acceptance of non-governmental organizations such as the Farm
Association and
micro finance establishments as an authorised partner on the state and
donor
support programs. The latter is possible, because the current Kazakh
legislation does not forbid for considering NGO as an agent or a
partner on the
state programs.
The proposed land reform with supporting
strategy aims to contribute
to further development of the small farmers and growth to optimal
efficiency level
of operation, which would allow them to be sustainable. This could be
done through
the Farm Association through establishment of the Farm Support Service
Centre, which
would provide
the farmers with needed consulting services in farm management, legal
and
financial issues. The local braches of the Farm Association would be
intermediary units
in providing access of these farms to the state support programs and
organising
short-term financing from the financial establishment and trading
companies. Also,
these branches might be driving wheel in the creation of the small
agricultural producers
co-operatives in sales of agricultural commodities and this
co-operation
would be applied in the purchase of inputs in the large quantities,
because
these would
provide a good price both cases.
The facilitation of the rural resident’s
access in getting land
tenure is needed, because the current legal framework for getting land
tenure
makes it impossible to the ordinary rural residents. The land
legislation
established some requirements to the applicants in getting land tenure
such
submittal of the business plan, proofs of the agricultural experience
and
presence of the relevant education or completion of special courses in
farming.
The strategy proposes to provide the rural residents, who wishing to be
involved in farming with relevant training at a specialised high
establishment
and college, because these requirements, established by the state are
reasonable.
Hence, before granting land tenure the state is to provide these people
with
the relevant training in farming at expenses of the state budget.
In the framework of state governance announced
decentralisation the
further strengthening the Agency for Land Resource Management raion
branches would
be logical. If these branches would be authorised to issue land tenure
to the applicants
it is necessary to provide them with additional facilities and
necessary empowerment.
The training, additional increase of staff would be a key part of
proposed institutional
strengthening of these branches. The delegation of more empowerments to
the local
branches in conducting the all relevant work such search of a land
plot, a contract
preparation would speed the process of land tenure granting. The
proposed institutional
strengthening of raion branches would be made through additional state
financing and this also would be a subject of “political will” of the
Government. Currently, the staff of raion branches is involved in the
current process
of land management, except process of land granting, which is priority
of the Agency
for Land Resources Management regional branches.
As this research project is relevant to the
legal issues the proposed
land reform suggests proposals for introducing some changes in the land
legislation. The proposals are served to defence the poor part of rural
residents against the harmful provisions of the introduced land reform.
The proposed
provision, forbidding sales of these rural residents business share in
the agricultural
business, would defend these people from loosing their business shares
for
getting money for their living.
The proposal
for reducing the cost of land plot acquisition into private
ownership would stimulate the purchases of the agricultural lands in
the regions,
where climatic conditions are not so favourable for crop growing. The
more complicated issue is an appraisal of the contributed land
shares into a statutory fund of the business entities. This issue
revokes the
necessity to introduce fairer methodology of these contributed land
shares appraisal,
because it would provide the rural residents with the adequate
financial means
for covering their basic needs for proper living.
The
research paper intends to
prevent the poorest part of rural residents from negative impact from
the
introduced Land Code with its harmful provisions in regards of the land
shares,
which were given by the state during the privatisation of former state
farms. The
introduced Land Code advances the land reform and embraces the all
aspects of
land reform, but the legislators did not take into consideration the
all
possible social outcomes for ordinary rural residents. Therefore,
the current land legislations is to be supported with some provisions
in the
land legislation, defending the rights of the ordinary rural residents
and proposals
for strengthening the public institutions and local braches of the
Agency for
Land Resources Management, which would contribute to the development of
rural
areas in Kazakhstan and to the growth of well- being of the rural
residents.
Literature
1. AbdraimovB.Zh.Land Process in Republic of Kazakhstan, Almaty, 2001.
2. Agency
of the Republic of Kazakhstan, Statistical Yearbook of Kazakhstan, 2002.
3. Agency
of the Republic of Kazakhstan, Regions of Kazakhstan, 2002.
4. Asian
Development Bank, TA No 2356 “Strengthening the Implementation
of Agriculture
Sector Reforms”, Danagro Advisor a/s,
September 1996.
5. Asian
Development Bank, TA No 3898-KAZ “Participatory Rural Sector Planningand Development“, Scanagri,February
2003.
6. Asian
Development Bank TA No 6078- REG “Rural Finance in Central Asia”, 2004.
7. Centre
of System Research of Administration of the President of Republic
of Kazakhstan, Land Code (informative support to
rural
area), Astana, 2004.
8. Espolov
T. E., Grigoruk V.V. Formation of Market System of Land Relations in Kazakhstan.
9. Hadzhiev A.H., Land Legislation of the Republic of Kazakshtan, 2002.
10. Rural
Population of Kyzylorda oblast: a Portrait in Numbers 2002.
11. UNDP,
Human Development Report, Kazakhstan 2002.
12. UNDP,
Poverty in Kazakhstan: Causes and Cures, Kazakhstan, 2004.
13. RDI
Report on Foreign Aid and Development # 119, The Impact of Land Titling
in Ukraine: An examination of the Results from
800 Person-Sample Survey, 2003.
14.World Bank, Land Reform in Ukraine, Washington, D.C.,1997.