Introduction
The Republic
of Kazakhstan has a territory of 2 724,900
sq. km, which makes in the ninth largest country in the world, roughly
the same
size as western Europe. Kazakhstan is totally landlocked (11). The
country is one huge plain, sloping from north east to south west. The
plain is
bordered by extensive mountain ranges on
the east and south-eastern borders. Its neighbours are Russia in the north and west, China in the east, and Kyrgyzstan, Turkmenistan and Uzbekistan in the south. Rural
Kazakhstan accounts for over 95 percent of Kazakhstan’s territory, or approximately 260
million hectares (6). Kazakhstan lies between the Siberian Taiga in
the north and the Central
Asia deserts in the
south, the Caspian Sea in the west and the mountain range
of the Tien-Shan and Altay in the east.
Kazakhstan has a continental climate; average temperatures
in the north – 18C in
January, while average temperatures
in the
south are of –3C in January. Summers
are generally dry and the average
temperature in July increases
gradually from 19C in the north to 28-30C in the south. Precipitation
in plain
areas is generally low from 400 mm annually in the north to 100 mm
annually in
the southwest. In the mountainous regions, the precipitation ranges
from
400-1600 mm (5).
As a result of these factors, Kazakhstan has three principal ecosystems:
desert areas, accounting for approximately 55 percent of rural areas;
the
steppe (grassland), accounting for approximately 30 percent; and
mountains and
foothills, accounting for the remaining 15 percent (6). These
ecosystems
provide a varied base for rural economic development encompassing
agriculture,
fishing, hunting, recreation/tourism, extractive industries and the
further
processing of natural raw materials (5).
The Kazakhstan’s climate makes possible to
cultivate wheat, barley, oats and rye in most regions. Irrigated land
in the
southern regions provides the growing temperature sensitive crops such
as
cotton, tobacco, rice, sugar beet, grapes and other fruits. Natural
pastures
accounts for 187, 9 million of hectares of land, which is enough to
feed 70,5
million head of sheep or 7,05 million cattle. Kazakhstan’s climate is favourable for
live-stock farming. It is traditional
occupation of Kazakh people and most pastures have been utilised during
the
year as a forage base (11).
Agriculture
in Kazakhstan is the largest industry in the national
economy occupying an important position in the social-economic politics
of the state.
Approximately 43, 7 percent of the population (total 14,9 million) live
in
rural area and 30,9 percent of the rural population live on less than
the minimum
subsistence income (approximately $ 35 USD per month) (6). At present,
the
total farmland is 222 million hectares and the average population
density is
under 6 people per square kilometre. Approximately 84,5 million
hectares of
agricultural land has been distributed to land users, including 20,5
million
hectares of arable land.
In 2003, Kazakhstan has introduced the private land
ownership by adopting a Land Code. According to this Land Code the
temporary
and permanent land use rights for agricultural land have been
supplemented with
private land ownership. Thus the Land Code outlined the forms of land
tenure
for agricultural lands both land use right and private ownership. The
objective
of this land reform is to establish efficient system in agricultural
sectors,
which will contribute to growth of agricultural production, people
welfare in
rural area and development of the land market.
Economic
transformation of the Kazakhstan economy has brought many changes to
the agricultural production and the rural economy. Employment
opportunities
have been severely affected by disintegration of economic relations
between
former republics of the Soviet
Union and the
concomitant fall in production. Further problems originated
with various constraints on the ability to sell agricultural
commodities on the
internal and external market at appropriate prices. The numbers of
unemployed
people have increased significantly after conducted restructuring and
privatization of state and collective enterprises and the abilities of
the
state to help such people are very limited. Thus agricultural reforms,
including land privatization are considered an important and key issue
in the
overall transformation of the economies of the former socialist world
(15).
During
2002-2003 the President of the Republic of Kazakhstan approved two large scale national programs:
the National State Agrofood Program for 2003-2005 and the National
Rural
Development Program for 2004-2010. In addition, the President announced
in
April 2002 that years of 2003-2005 would be Kazakhstan’s “Years of Rural Revival”. Also,
the Government has paid a great deal of attention for transforming
agricultural
production into a stable factor for economic growth. Three main
priorities have
been designated for development of rural area:
- providing
food security;
- a gradual increasing in
agricultural
production and the growth of sales on either
- the internal market and international market;
- establishment of proper
living conditions in
the countryside (7).
Irrespective
of whether the Government spends sufficient amount of funds on existing
state
support programs, the main tasks of agrarian reforms at this stage are
the completion
of rural land reform and the
creation
of the necessary legislative base for private landowners to use the
land efficiently. The land use rights together with
uncertainty and instability of recent land legislation did little to
stimulate
or enhance the quality of land and attract long term investments in the
agrarian sector (7).
The
experience of many developed
countries has shown that way of economic
prosperity depends on the effective implementation of agrarian reforms,
particular land reforms. The greatest reform progress has been made by
those countries
that are reforming in very large steps, which are provided by political
will of
authorities. It is relevant for countries of Central and Eastern Europe. On the contrary, CIS countries implement
the agrarian reforms in the way of a gradual approach. There has only
slight
progress in the core countries of the CIS countries and consequently
the
agrarian reforms have not met the original expectation (16). Thus there
are
some needs for further steps in the agrarian reforms in CIS countries,
including Kazakhstan in order to increase the
agricultural production that in turn will develop the rural sector and
contribute to welfare of the rural habitants.
The aim
of this paper is to investigate the economic and social aspects of land
reform
in Kazakhstan. The
following issues are to be considered in this paper:
- the
economic transformation of agriculture during last decade and the
introduction peasant
farms since the early 1990s, the
privatization of state agricultural enterprises, the distribution of
land
shares to inhabitants of the rural areas;
- the
regulatory framework for each stages of
land reforms, the institutional bases that have been established to
strengthen the
legal basis for land relations and to encourage entrepreneurial
initiatives in
agricultural production, desirable state support policies to farms and
peasants
farms to help in achieving sustainability in their farming activities;
- potential
impact of land reform on poor households and considering
way to mitigate the most negative impacts,
an analysis of proposed alternative policy scenarios and
the
identification of appropriate and sound policies in land issues.
1. Land Legislation Development
in Kazakhstan
1.1. Overall Review of Land
Legislation Development.
As in
other countries of the CIS, the land reform in Kazakhstan, is concerned
with
developing a legal and institutional framework, which will allow the
transfer of
real property assets (land and structures built on land) from state
control to
a variety of legal entities(4). This transference of land and property
assets
was made by means of land and property shares as in other CIS
countries.
The
Law
on Land and Land Relations has been replaced several times by
authorised legislative
acts such as the Presidential Decrees and Laws of the Republic of Kazakhstan. The first attempt to reform land
relations was taken by the Supreme Council of the Kazakh Soviet Republic with introduction of the Land Code in
November 1990. Despite this Land Code maintaining the dominance of
state
ownership of land, it did ensure various essential changes in land
arrangement
some of the key features by providing citizens with the right to
possession for
life of land plot for a peasant farm, for construction, for subsistence
production, horticulture and cattle breeding, summer cottage
construction and
traditional handicraft.
Before
the Land Code was introduced, the Law “On Peasant Farm in the Kazakh
Soviet
Republic” (21, May 1990) established the peasant farm (private family
farm) as
an independent farming entity, provided peasant farms (private family
farm) an
independent farming entity ensuring that it would enjoy equality with
other
business entities in agriculture. This meant that the organizational
and the
legal form of non-state agricultural farming entity were introduced
into the
practice of the country. The Law set out the principles of
organization, the activity
of peasant farms, declared its business independence and stated that
produced
commodities and received income are the property of peasant farms and
could
used by their own discretion. Life inheritable tenure for a land plot
was
introduced for private family farms, based on labour contribution of
each
member and joint ownership on the productive tools and property.
According to
this Law the land plot under life inheritable tenure is not divisible
and it could
not be subject of a sale, exchange, lease and transference as a gift to
external persons. The land plot might be transferred to member of this
family
peasant farm due to inability of the head of peasant farm to work
because of achievement
of pension age or losing the ability to work. The
land plot should be inherited to successor
in case of deaf of the head of the peasant farm. All those transfers of
land
plots to inheritors were made possible by the introduction of the Civil
Code at
the end of 1994. When the Civil Code took an effect on March 1995,
those who
had been granted lifetime inheritable tenure status were allowed to
sell, gift
or lease their land. The same legislation allowed the transfer of life
inheritable tenure rights to the capital stock of an enterprise (4).
The next Law “On land reform in
the Kazakh
Soviet Republic” (28, June 1991) was intended to create economic and
social
conditions for effective functioning of various business entities,
involved in
farming and to ensure rational land use and to achieve stable increase
in agricultural
commodities production. (8). This law provided for the basic the basic
norms of
land redistribution as regards state enterprises privatization and the
reorganization
of collective farms. The land legislation created a special land fund
for local
representative bodies to grant land for life to those wishing to use
the land for
farming, private ancillary farm, cattle breeding, horticulture, or
construction
were introduced in this land
legislation. The special land fund was created mainly through the
withdrawal of
“irrationally” used land (9).
The Presidential
Decree “On Some Issues of Land Relation Regulation” (# 1516, 24 January
of
1994) provided that land parcels could be granted to citizens and legal
entities for temporary use for up to 5 years (short-term rent) and up
to 99
years (long term rent). In both cases, the user would need to pay rent.
This decree
also set out the rights of citizens and legal entities for purchasing
land use
rights or renting them in the case of privatization of non –
agricultural real
estate.
The 1994 Presidential Decree “On Further
Improvement of Land Relations” (#1639, 5 April of 1994) allowed that
citizens
and legal entities could sell, rent out or pledge their various lands
rights as
collateral. They were also entitled to sell these abovementioned rights
to statutory
fund of joint stock companies, to partnerships, co-operatives,
including those
that included foreign participation. In this way, land use rights
became the subject
of sales, purchases and other property transaction. This decree could
be seen
as a significant step in adapting land relations to market conditions
and
created legal basis for a land market.
The Presidential
Decree (having the force of law, in this case) “On land“ was adopted
December 22nd
1995 and was the first the first legislative act on land relations,
which complied
with the basic legislative acts such as the Constitution of Republic of
Kazakhstan and the Civil Code, (in effect in March 1995). Thus the new
introduced
institutions of land ownership were legally bound to the abovementioned
basic
legal act.
In
this Law “On land” citizens and legal entities had the right to acquire
a land
parcel for private ownership and land was recognized as real estate and
all transactions
were permitted with these land parcels. At the same time forest land,
and land
relating to water resources fund, land under settlements and especially
protected natural reserves remained under the state ownership. Land
parcels
were granted to citizens for certain purposes, such as conducting own
subsidiary farms, horticulture and summer residence construction. As
concerned
legal entities land parcels were granted to them for technological
needs,
particular for the construction of structures on land and construction
of
living houses.
Farmland
remained under the state ownership. Non-state legal entities and
citizens had
the right to acquire land plots with permanent land use rights while
secondary
land users and foreign entities had the right to possess land plots on
a scheme
of temporary land use rights for between 3 years and up to 99 years.
The
new property institutions such as the right to private ownership on
lands,
permanent land use rights, the right for limited use of other land
parcel
(servitude) and condominium have appeared in the land legislation of
the Republic of Kazakhstan.
The
third stage of land reform legislation in Kazakhstan was characterized by the adoption
of a substantial number of legal acts. After introducing the Law “On
land”
approximately 100 legislative acts were adopted, creating the
legislative infrastructure
for market land relations. This has not been changed significantly by
further
laws and measures. Some acts were introduced to support and reinforce
private
ownership on land, use of land by non-state legal entities, the
creation and
defence of the land market, and for ensuring state control for the
purpose of
safe and rational use of land. All these legislative acts were brought
in to
transform land relations in conjunction with emerging market conditions
(9).
Despite its breadth the Law ”On
land” was limited by the Constitution of Kazakhstan, which provided
that the Presidential
Decrees were valid until the relevant law was adopted by the Parliament
of the
Republic of Kazakhstan. The necessity to issue the Presidential Decrees
at the
end of 1995 was explained by fact, that the Constitutional Court recognized the election of deputies
to the Parliament as illegitimate by its decision and therefore the
Parliament
was dissolved by the President. Then the President had taken the power
to issue
laws in the form of a presidential decree. On 24th January
2001 the Parliament
adopted a new Law “On Land” and this Law replaced the previous Law ”On
Land” of
1995.
After
adopting the Law “On land” of 2001 the institution of land use rights
was
changed significantly. The permanent land use right of citizens and
non-state
legal entities was cancelled and the duration of long term temporary
land use
rights was reduced from 99 years to 49 years. At the beginning of the
land
reforms peasant farms had the right of inheritable land tenure for
life,
subsequently, they were given permanent land use rights and finally
they were
allotted only temporary land use rights. The Law “On Land” of 2001
retained the
possibility of permanent land use right only for state land users. Thus
the
rights of landuser, particular the peasant farms were worsened by this
introduced law.
Some
essential differences in land tenure between state and non-sate
landusers were
established by the new legislation. The latter were allowed to alienate
their land
use rights by their own discretion, to rent out their land use rights,
pledge
the land to another and implement all other deals with respect to their
land
use rights. Thus the non-state landusers with its temporary land use
rights had
a status, very close to private ownership. On
the contrary, state legal entities as permanent
landusers were restricted
in such business deals and only can do it only by the consent of the
authorized
state bodies. This Law enlarged the sphere of responsibility in land
relations.
While
increasing the scope of legal freedom also this Law enlarged the sphere
of
responsibility in land relations. New sanctions were introduced in the
form of
more sophisticated property penalties that took into account the type
of infringement,
the size of damage and the degree of public danger.
In
addition to these measures land zoning was introduced in this law.
Accordingly,
ten zones were determined on the territory of Kazakhstan and these
vary from forestry to steppe zone to central Asian mountain and
southern
Siberian mountain, including deserted and subtropical-deserted zones.
This zone
specialization of land in Kazakhstan has had a
strong influence on the development of land legislation, binding other
interrelated legal norms and documents.
This
land legislation retained certain functions to organize and provide for
rational
land use and land protection. The role of state remained considerable
and its main
functions can be laid out in the following:
-
determination
of state policy in the area of use and protection of the land fund of
Republic;
-
establishment of the legal regime of land,
proceeding from the categorisation of
land by its designation;
- establishing
measures to govern the condition
of sales of land ownership and land
tenure for agricultural land;
- planning
of land use;
- establishment,
change and termination of
land use rights in cases established by
legislation;
- implementation
of control for right use and protection of
land;
- implementation
of land monitoring, land
cadastre and land arrangement.
- solving
land disputes;
- determining
the liabilities and consequences
for land legislation offences.
In 2003, Kazakhstan introduced private land ownership
by means of adoption of the Land Code. According to this Land Code the
temporary and permanent land use rights, which were established
previously in
land tenure for agricultural land were supplemented with the addition
of private
land ownership. The Land Code of 2003 outlined the forms of land tenure
for
agricultural land and provided for farms and faming entities to enjoy
land
tenure by means of private land ownership or temporary land use right.
The aim
of the introduction of private ownership for agricultural lands was to
further
promote the development of market relations in rural areas and so help
to
create a land market, which will facilitate the transition of
agricultural land
to efficient agricultural producers.
1.2 Ownership of Land.
“The
concept of ownership is fundamental to the realisation of an assets
full
economic potential (4)”. With these
words land ownership is made a cornerstone to agrarian reforms. Given
the
important role that land plays in transition, the very concept of land
ownership
ought to be considered. Under the Civil Code “ownership” is very close
to Roman
Law and combines the ability to:
-
freely acquire or dispose of an assets,
either by purchase/ sales or gift;
-
possess an asset in the sense that it
contributes to the enhancement of an entity’s
worth;
-
use an asset to provide benefit, either in
cash or kind (4).
“In
1991 the Constitution (Article 46) stated that all land in Kazakhstan was the property of the state and
as a consequence all other forms of “ownership” were at the discretion
of the
state (4)”. The Land Code of 1991 did not intend to embrace the Roman
law
concept of ownership. The land reforms at this time were concerned with
the
transfer of land plots to the various form categories of permanent
ownership,
which was restricted to state enterprises lifetime, inheritable tenure,
temporary and permanent use, and leasing.
From
1991 to 1995 the abovementioned categories of land ownership and use
remained
in force. Attempts were made to bring these categories closer to the
Roman law
definition by relaxing the terms and conditions of ownership.
Nevertheless, the
provisions of the 1991 Land Code remained legal vacuum because there
was no
legal basis for fundamental terminology such as “ownership”
(non-state),
“inheritance” and “enterprise” (4).
By
introducing the Civil Code in 1994 made significant change step towards
a Roman
definition of ownership. However, in practice all land transaction such
as
purchase, sale lifetime inheritable tenure agreements remained the
subject to
administrative approval. Similarly, the local administration retained
the right
to determine the value and other terms of any sale (4).
The main weaknesses of this approach was that
the actual granting of land to citizens for creating peasant farms was
conducted
at the discretion of the local representative bodies and subject to
their to regulate
and control all transactions.
Articles
24 of the 1991 Land Code contained a long list of reasons why an
individual
could be deprived of previously granted land rights. Many of these
conditions
were couched in broad term that gave local authorities considerable
interpretative freedom. There were cases of individuals having their
land
rights rescinded or changed hereby introducing uncertainty into the
process (4).
The Civil
Code (legally in force March 1995) provided the legal basis for
private
sector entrepreneurial activity such as the right to non-state
ownership, the right
to establish business enterprises and etc. However, with respect to
land the
Civil Code (Article 193) reiterated the exclusive right of the state to
such
ownership. This position was consistent with both previous legislation
and the
Constitution at that time (4).
The
introduction of a new Constitution of Republic of Kazakhstan, adopted
by
national referendum on August 30th 1995 provided that in addition to
state
ownership of land, there was the possibility of agricultural land being
held
under private ownership. The new
Constitution guaranteed the equality and equal defence of state and
private
ownership. These constitutional norms became the ground for the
creation of
new, more market oriented land legislation.
This
constitutional norm enabled a Presidential Decree “On Land” to be
issued in December
1995 on which limited private ownership of land was introduced. Private
ownership was allowed for personal households plot, gardens and dachas.
However, land of agricultural value (except for the households plots
previously
mentioned) may not be granted for private ownership status and this
included
peasant farms. At that time peasant farms fell into the category of
permanent
use and were provided with permanent land use rights.
The
administrative regulation and control of land transaction were weakened
by the adoption
of this Law “On Land”. Henceforth, it was possible for two parts to
legally
agree the purchase or sale of a land plot between themselves at a
mutually
agreed price and to have the transaction notarised without
administrative
interference. This legislation sought to limit administrative abuses
such as changing
or rescinding land rights yet ownership
and use rights could still be rescinded for certain offences, such as
violating
land use assignment categories, using agricultural land for
non-agricultural purposes,
causing ecological damages or as a sanction for a criminal convicted of
a
criminal offence (4).
The
next Law “On land“ in 2001 did not make any substantial changes in the
concept
of ownership. Permanent land use rights were replaced by long term and
short
terms temporary land use rights with state enterprises being granted
the
permanent land use right. Non-state land users held the right to rent
out their
land use rights for periods not exceeding their lease period with
state. Also,
the non-state land users had the same rights to sell, exchange, gift
and pledge
as collateral. These temporary land use rights are very close to
previously
established permanent land use rights although from an economic and
common
sense perspective the switch from permanent to temporary land use is
difficult
to understand. The replacement of
permanent land use rights was made without any clear explanation and no
commentators have been able to find any reason that could explain this
change
in land use rights.
The
land legislation began in 1990 with the introduction of the concept of
lifetime
inherited land tenure. Then Government introduced permanent land use
rights.
This was promising in terms of developing a land market. The introduced
temporary land use right undermined
the sustainability of land tenure
and it gave less confidence to owners that their land plot would not
taken by
officials some time in the future or that the conditions of land tenure
would
not renewed as they had been granted. Thus the Government changed land
legislation to the direction, which has deteriorated the status of
landusers.
It
is necessary to note that provisions of “On land” of 1995 and ”On Land”
of 2001
did not contain the legal norms for the obligatory replacement of
documents, proving
the land tenure. The 1995 Law “On Land” provided the legal documents,
proving
the right of citizens and legal entities and issued before adoption of
this
edict would be remain in force while the 2001 Law “On Land” provided
that the
process of renewing documents from permanent to temporary status would
be at
the request of the landusers.
Despite
these provisions on the status of pre-existing documents various state
bodies
forced landusers to change their legal documents from the permanent
land use
right and lifetime inheritable possession to the temporary land use
rights both
for legal entities and peasant farms. Thus the Kazakh authorities they
did not respect
the plurality of land ownership, which were promulgated in previous
land laws.
1.3. State Farm
Privatization.
Farm
privatization took place in several phases as in other CIS countries.
Although
the farm privatisation was concerned with transforming state
agricultural
enterprises the privatisation legislation concerned other forms of
agricultural
enterprise as well. It should be noted that the farm privatisation
legislative
framework evolved in a piecemeal approach rather than introducing a
single
comprehensive set of laws with determinate outcome.
Early
farm privatisation phase began in 1990 with adopting the Law on Peasant
Farms
and the entire process was placed in the hands of local
administrations. Land
for creating these peasant farms was either appropriated from state
agricultural enterprise or allocated out of a special land fund
established for
this purpose. The legislation contributed to creation of several
hundreds farms
in the form of individually or family owned farms. As this process was
made
without having all the necessary guidelines and procedure the
implementation of
farm privatization was highly subjective (4). The result was that not
so many
people believed that the lifetime inherited land tenure would remain in
the
business environment, which remained under state control and maintained
the
principle of the command economy. In addition, employment in the state
agricultural enterprises was self-sufficient for many and preferable to
taking
the entrepreneurial risks, associated with private farming.
In 1992 legislation set out how
privatisation of state farms could be more equitable than before.
Privatisation
was to be achieved, primarily through the distribution of assets to
employees
(current, retired and ancillary). All those entitled would receive land
shares
providing an equal amount of land. Similarly the property of state
enterprises
was allocated in the form of asset shares expressed in monetary terms
taking
salary, years of service and professional skills into account. The
owners of
shares could use them to:
- form
individual (family) farms;
- contribute
to the capital stock of joint stock
companies, co-operatives or
collective enterprises;
- sell
or exchange with other
shareholders.
This
process was placed in the hands of the State Property Committee (4).
This
legislation had limited success. One of the reasons why the
privatisation of
state agricultural enterprises did not meet the intended expectation
was that
enterprise legislation, allowing the creation of various types of
business was
not adopted. Only the Civil Code, which came into force in March 1995,
laid
down the basic freedom of entrepreneurial activity and defined the
various
forms of business enterprises including: partnerships, limited
partnerships and
joint –stock company. These forms as well as productive cooperatives
were
described in the Civil Code but during 1992 -1994 farm employees had
very
restricted legal options and were often unaware about all the options
available
to them (4).
By 1994
it was clear that farm privatisation legislation was not succeeding in
creating
significant numbers of viable new farms. The majority of former state
agricultural enterprises merely underwent a change of name. In an
attempt to
speed up the process new legislation was passed (4). The Presidential
Decree
“Concerning the Transference of sovkhozes Property Part to Director
Ownership”
(1585, March of 1994) allowed the transfer of 10 % of the land shares
of an
enterprise to the farm director, who had held the position of director
for
twenty years. A further 10 % could be allocated on a temporary basis
and then
transferred to full ownership after five years of satisfactory
performance. The
Government Resolution (216, February of 1994) also allowed the sale of
selected
agricultural enterprises to individuals through closed tender. Some 34
sovkhozes were selected and about 20 sovkhozes were sold into private
ownership. Each buyer was allocated 20 % of the equity and employees 49
%. The
remaining 31 % was held by the state and allocated to the buyer under
certain
conditions. The buyer was required to assume the debts of the farm.
These two
procedures were temporary measures which were not longer applicable,
because
the conditions of closed tenders were not appropriate to potential
owners of
these state and collective enterprises.
In 1995
the farm legislation framework became more consistent, when various
parts of
legislation were put together. This farm privatisation legislation was
based
upon the same principles of equitable distribution of land and assets
shares,
but with the added benefit that the various forms of business
enterprise, which
could be adopted, had a basis in the civil law. Broadly, the various
forms of
business had definitions similarly to those in market economies.
By the
middle of 1996 and according to official statistics 2332 state
agricultural
enterprises had been privatised and 6050 new farming entities had been
established by new owners on the territory and farmland of these state
enterprises. The conversion rate of approximately 1:2,6. The most
significant
types of non-state farming entities were collective enterprises, small
enterprises and co-operatives. The term of collective enterprise was
used by
local authorities to distinguish a new voluntary association of
shareholders
from the old state agricultural enterprises. In practise, these
associations
usually conveyed a change of the name and modest re-organization and
little
else. The same management and farming activities were pursued. These called collective enterprises and joint
stock companies retained about three quarters of the land and assets of
the
privatised state agricultural enterprises. In other words, three
quarters of
agricultural production assets did not change their economic and social
status.
The conversion of state agricultural enterprises into peasant farms did
not
proceed at the desired level and the number of newly created peasant
farms
amounted to only 1591 units for the same period, which was less than
the actual
number of privatised agricultural enterprises (4). All those newly
established
farming entity obtained the land under permanent land use rights. As
these
collective enterprises have been owned by
The
further stages of farm privatisation were characterised that
restructuring,
mainly of these collective enterprises was left by “market forces” with
the
increasingly active involvement of private businesses. The relevant
market
legislation had been developed by legislation and farm privatisation
and
restructuring took its place in the framework of civil legislation with
additional legislative acts, considering the specific features of
agricultural
production. Where climatic and marketing conditions were favourable
some farms
were successfully restructured by their management and private
businesses.
Considerable proportions of farms though were subject to bankruptcy and
liquidation procedures.
A significant
number of private trading businesses were suppliers of input for
agricultural
production mainly in the form of fuel and seed. They were often
involved in
informal financing of agricultural enterprises or barter trading. The
terms of
seasonal financing and trading barter were largely unfavourable for
agricultural enterprises. Owing to the predatory terms of barter
contract and
short-term financing provided by trading companies the collective
enterprises
were usually heavily indebted. It was
the only option for agricultural producer under trading companies and
furthermore there was no assess to either state or banking financing. The result was that many of these
agricultural collective enterprises failed to meet their contractual
obligations under such contract with the trading companies and the
majority of
these enterprises were acquired by creditors. The shareholders and
workers of
these enterprises could withdraw the land designated in their land
shares
alongside their property shares but they were obliged to take part of
debts of
agricultural enterprises in an amount of corresponding to their share
of
participation. The result was that shareholder and workers had to leave their
land shares in business entities, established by these private
businessmen. In
this way private businesses entered into the agricultural sectors and
assumed a
dominant position in agricultural production.
As result
of these actions shareholding became to concentrate in the hand of
former
senior personnel, administrations or private businessmen. And
additional reason
was that many land shareholders, particularly pensioners and social
workers
used their land share rights for leasing. For this they received rental
payments, mainly in kind, which covers the basic needs in food and
animal
breeding such as feed and hay.
A mutual
economic dependency developed between land share owners and newly
established
private enterprises. Land shareowners require inputs (animal feed, seed
end
etc) acquired from private enterprises to sustain their personal
subsidiary
plot and cattle breeding activities. Also, the decision to transfer
land shares
to large private entities in the form of a lease was based on the
possibility
that the land share owner could be employed by this farm either
permanently or
temporarily for seasonal work. This employment provided rural citizens
with
cash, which was very important because of the absence of other
alternatives in
the rural area. Thus, farm privatization legislation contributed to the
creation of new private agricultural enterprises, which occupied
considerable
farmland for agricultural production mainly through the lease of land
shares
from rural inhabitants.
In 1998
all newly appeared non-state enterprises of different categories were
required
to be re-registered in order to be comply with the Civil Code. By the end of 1998 in percentage, 69, 3 % of
the agricultural and arable land belonged to large-scale enterprises
such as
limited partnerships, agricultural co-operatives and joint stock
companies (2).
These large-scale enterprises are the backbone of agricultural
production at
present. In many cases, the ownership or majority of shares of this
type of
enterprises are in the hand of one person or certain business groups.
Thus farm
privatization ended with up with emerging private businesses, which had
sufficient funds and funding from commercial banks and access to local
and
republican authorities. At the same time huge number (95 460 as of
1.01.2002) of peasant farms appeared in the agricultural sectors. This
amount However,
the amount of agricultural land under the land tenure of peasant farms
is
considerably less than that held in private business entities.
1.4 Land Sharing
The land
sharing mechanism was designed to be a tool for the equitable
distribution of
land and assets of former state agricultural enterprises in the
framework of the
state properties privatization program among rural inhabitants and
former
workers of these enterprises. Thus the land share mechanism was an
attempt by
legislators to distribute the state property to formers workers of this
enterprise and other people, involved directly and indirectly in this
enterprise or living in the village, where the enterprise had operated.
Employees
of former state agricultural enterprises, employees of enterprise of
social
infrastructure and retired workers were entitled to obtain a share of
the
farm’s land and the assets of their enterprises, which were firstly
mentioned
in the farm legislation of 1992. This land and assets shares may be
identified
physically or may remain as a paper shareholding depending upon the
choices of
the employee and the corporate nature of the privatised enterprise.
The
average size of land share was determined by dividing the total land
area of an
agricultural enterprise by the number of those entitled. The right to a
land
share was determined by the privatized enterprise which presented a
list of
those entitled to the head of local administration. Once approved, the
list was
used by the regional branch of Land State Committee to issue land share
certificates, which represented a nominal right to obtain a land plot
of state
or collective enterprise owned agricultural land. The
final size of an individual land share
depends upon the agro-ecological zone and type of farm, but is commonly
between
20-50 hectares on the northern region whereas in the southern region,
the average
size of land share varies between 2- 15 hectares. The smallest land
shares are
those for irrigated land (4).
The
invention of the “land share” was common to many countries of the
former Soviet Union reflected some of the former rules
and principle of the socialistic system. The definition of “land share”
together
with “property share” was first mentioned in the Resolution of the
Government
(№ 633, 20, July 1993) “On Measures on Implementation of the
Presidential
Decree “On the National Program of Privatization in the Republic of
Kazakhstan
for 1993-1995 years (№ 1135, 5, March 1993)”, which specified that
rural
inhabitants may have the land and property share of state enterprise in
framework of the national program of privatization. The rural
inhabitants have
a right to own land as “collective” property and they may withdraw
their “land
share” in kind. Also, these land shares were eligible to lease,
bequeath it,
but not to sell it. The Resolution of
the Government «On approval the procedure of concession of land
share on
privatization of state agricultural enterprises” (№ 611, 10, June 1994)
allowed
sales and transference of property shares and only the concession of
the land
shares to other member of collective enterprise for using these land
shares for
agricultural production. This provision provided the safeguard the
wholeness of
agricultural property complex in collective ownership.
The Civil
Code did not specify the land shares rights as an independent legal
element
with specified attribute and right to ownership. The land legislation
made no
provision for the land share to be registered officially and only a
land share
certificate ought to be issue. This land share certificates did not
provide the
precise location of land plot with a demarcated land border and other
attributes of land plot and it provides the holder only size of land
plot. Thus
the land share existed in framework of collective enterprises and
served as a
legal arrangement for transferring the property and land from state to
private
businesses. Later an Article 82 of the 2001 Law “On Land” defined the
legal
status of land shares and it reiterated the same essence of land
sharing
mechanism that was promulgated in the early land legislation.
A huge
number of rural habitants became the land share owners since the start
of agricultural
reforms in 1991. According to the statistics approximately 2.3 million
land
share were distributed to rural people. Approximately 60 % of those
land shares
were transferred to workers of liquidated, privatized and restructured
state
enterprises and 40% to workers, serving these enterprises and living in
its
territory and pensioners.
Only a
small proportion of peasants took the opportunity to become landowners
and work
on land. Large proportions however hold the same rights for lands, but
are unable
to actually farm the land. Those people faced with the problem of how
to manage
their land shares. The number of such people has been increasing every
year due
to the retirement of older people and migration to urban area and
others
reasons. These circumstances provided the private legal entities with
possibility to lease land shares from rural habitants. This lease
agreement
provided the land share holders with lease payments, which usually are
very low
and mainly paid in kind. Also, the current land legislation did provide
the holders
of land share with the possibility of withdrawal of their land share in
order
to establish an individual farm or to pool their shares or to take the
land
plot for the establishment of partnership, co-operative or joint- stock
company.
The
division of land into shares allowed for the creation of large private
enterprises and the owners of these newly appeared enterprises were
able to
accumulate the shares of those rural habitants, who did not realise
their
rights were being used for organizing large scale business. Land share
privatization provided an opportunity for land consolidation in the
hand of
private business entities without any physical division of farmland,
thereby
allowing private businesses to retain large areas of farmland for
agricultural production.
Thus, the
distribution of land shares was an important instrument for
restructuring the
agricultural sector by transferring from state ownership into private
ownership, which is basis for a market economy and the further
development of
land relations.
2. Rural Kazakhstan
2.1 Land Resources.
In 1990
the total area of farmland in Kazakhstan was about 220 million hectares. Out
of this figure 35 million of land was cultivated and over 180 million
hectares
of steppe was utilised as grazing pasture for cattle breeding (2).
Following
land and agrarian reforms the agricultural economy suffered a deep
financial crisis
that lead to a decrease of the total area of cultivated land. Farmland
decreased in 2002 by 2,5 times in comparison with 1990 year and the
total area
of farmland is currently about 84,5 million hectares with arable land
accounting for 20,5 million hectares and the remaining land are used
for pasture and hayfields, amounting to 59
million
hectares and 2 million hectares
respectively(2).
The actual area of sustained competitive
rainfed agriculture remains an unanswered question. The area of good
quality
soils is about 12 million hectares, mostly in the north of the country,
but the
area with quality soils and normally adequate annual rainfall for
arable
farming is less. The area suited to rainfed agriculture is mainly
concentrated in
the north and east. Even in these areas the expectation is that one
year in
three or four will be one of inadequate rainfall. Thus, rainfed arable
agricultural activity in Kazakhstan is not only restricted,
geographically, but faces high risks from climatic uncertainties, which
impact on
the productive capacity of farming entities (5).
The natural resource base provides the
opportunity to irrigate substantial areas of reasonable quality soils,
which is
one way of reducing production risks. In
the early 1990s Kazakhstan had 2.3 million hectares of
irrigated land, which accounted for 6 % of total sown area, yielding up
to 30 %
of crop production. Subsequently, the area of irrigated agriculture has
been
reduced to 1.2 million hectares due to water shortages and
deterioration of the
infrastructure systems and yields have fallen 1.5-2 times. Most of the
irrigated area is concentrated in the southern part of the country and
has also
undergone a contraction. The land reclamation qualities of soil have
been
deteriorating, while the technical condition of water stations has also
worsened (11).
The third natural resource category is
permanent pasture (mostly steppe), which is the dominant natural
vegetation of Kazakhstan. This category covers 90% of the
country, but the quality of the pasture varies considerably depending
on soil
quality, temperature and rainfall regimes. The foothills of the
mountains and
parts of northern Kazakhstan support quality pasture but large
areas are arid and support only scrub vegetation. The scale and range
of
quality of the natural grasslands determines that livestock systems
must be the
dominant form of agricultural system over much of the country (5).
The natural environment that supports
agricultural
production systems is fragile due to past inadequate attention to
sustainable
production practices which meant that substantial areas of lands
suffered from
saline soils, water logging, soil erosion and desertification. The loss
of
quality topsoil over the past 30 years is well recognised and parts of
the
black soil area have lost up to 30% of their humus content (5).
The introduction of market norms through land
legislation has substantially
affected the reallocation of land categories in the agrarian sector.
The introduction
of private ownership, land tax and land use rights have forced
landusers to
optimise the size of their lands. The category of farmland has incurred
to
substantial changes and its land area has decreased to 136,2 million
hectares
in 2002 (2). Besides, the land tax, other reasons of land users refusal
from
land tenure were declining the sowing area due to high risks from climatic uncertainties and decrease of livestock production. Thus the return of these agricultural lands to
land reserve fund has taken place, mainly on pasture in semi-desert and
desert
area and on arable land in dry lands. The
total area of this fund has increased in 7 times
to compare with
1990 and its accounts for 127,3 million hectares as of 1, January 2002
(2).
2.2. Rural
Development Policy in Kazakhstan.
The process of agricultural reforms
in the country can be broken down into four stages. The period of
1992-1194 was
characterised by the rapid reform of agricultural entities. At this
stage the
creation of a new legal framework for privatisation and land reforms
were the
main goal of reformers, leading to the adoption of laws on land,
privatisation
and peasant farms (11).
By the end of 1994, as a result of
the privatization of collective and state agricultural enterprises the
number
of agricultural entities had increased. But, total agricultural output
did not
increase despite the establishment of alternatives forms of farming
entities
such as peasant farms and production co-operatives. The reason which
has been
described in detail above were a mixture of economic, legal and social
factors
which inhibited the efficient production and rational use of land (11).
The majority of the rural
population
were unready to accept reforms, which represented fundamental changes
in the
rural life-style (11). Existing technological links in the production
and in the
procurement of inputs and machinery were disrupted. The more serious
problem of
price disparity between industrial and agricultural products emerged as
a
direct result of government regulations whereby prices of industrial
goods and
services were liberalised whilst prices for agricultural commodities
were fixed
(4).
When agricultural prices were
finally liberalised in 1994 the higher prices led to a fall in consumer
purchasing power. Subsequently, high inflation led to the loss of
current and
partly fixed assets, mainly livestock as livestock owners slaughtered
cattle to
raise the cash. This was a starting point of rural out-migration.
The principle of continuity of
technological processes on farms, service providing farms and similarly
enterprises was broken. Several
factors
such as the accelerated privatisation of state agricultural
enterprises,
storage processing and service entities, limited business forms of
organization,
high inflation and unbalanced nature of sectors made the integration of
agriculture impossible, further reducing the efficiency of the
production
process.
The funds provided under a
framework of loan financing for newly established farms were
insufficient.
Furthermore, the state budget did not allocate additional funding for
the rural
sector in the framework of the 1991 Law ”On Prioritised Development of
Auls,
Villages and Agriculture”, which aimed to soften the consequences of
market
transition for rural economy (11).
In this way, inadequate
implementation of market reforms in agriculture from 1992-1994 led to a
fall in
agricultural output, the deterioration of the asset base and an
increase in
negative tendency in both production and social sector. It also led to
a significant
increase in the migration of the rural population to cities (11).
The period of 1995 -1997 was
characterised by an increasingly rapid fall in agricultural output due
to
declines in the cultivated area and decreasing livestock numbers and as
well as
low yield and productivity (11).
The private farms accounted for
93,5 % of all agricultural enterprises while the numbers of production
co-operatives
and agricultural enterprises were also
increased.
Before 1992 several hundred farms were set up with sufficient resources
base,
but during “mass privatisation” in period 1993 -95 the condition of
privatisation changed and most state agricultural enterprises were
deprived of
state support, thrown into free market and found themselves in debt. A
majority
of these state enterprises were heavily indebted and employees with
property
share found themselves partly to the debt share of enterprise. In this
situation
agricultural employees were often forced to sell or transfer their land
use
rights almost unconditionally and in many cases to creditors.
The already seriously complicated
situation in the agricultural sector was exacerbated by the
transference of the
accounting system from cash methods to accrued methods by Resolution of
Government “On transition to Accrued Methods in Tax Accounting” (1001, 20
June 1997). This
resulted in the bankruptcy of many insolvent farmers, because the
income tax on
accrued method was considerable more than the actual profit, which
farmers had
at the reporting date (11).
Investments in the agricultural
sectors were substantially reduced, because of sudden policy changes
and the transition
from state distribution of investment resources to market mechanisms.
Farms
were generally not profitable and they could not get a loan from the
banking
sector due to the instability and crisis in agricultural sector.
Government
measures were very limited and not very effective. Between 1995 -1997
gross
agricultural output declined by 38 % compared with 1992-1994, a fall
made up of
a 26 % reduction in crop farming and a 55 % drop in livestock farming
output
(11).
This decline in agricultural output
inevitably caused adverse social effects. Social tension and migration
away
from rural area, particularly younger people intensified. Average wages
in
agriculture were 3,8 times lower than in industry. Social
infrastructure in the
majority of villages was inadequate and did not satisfy basic needs.
After the “optimisation”
of education and health care sectors nearly 60 % of villages lost their
medical
care stations, libraries, clubs and more 50 % of rural settlement did
not have
any post offices (2).
The period of 1998-2000 saw several
positive changes in rural life since independence. More state support
was made
available for agricultural producers and agricultural enterprises began
to
receive the favourable loans and advance payment within the state
procurement
programs. 1999 was remarkable for the fact that agricultural production
grew
for the first time in several years and growth was at 28 % compared to
1998. The
decline in the number of cattle and horses slowed, while the
corresponding
number for pigs, sheep and goats began to increase (11).
Nevertheless, agricultural
producers were still constrained by the lack of guaranteed assess to
local
wholesale food markets, the low purchasing prices for their product,
the largely
depreciated asset base, limited financing options, high taxes,
depletion of
natural resources and low consuming power. Falling living standard and
higher
unemployment rates led to an increase in “self-employment”, which
amounted to 2
million people by 2001, although whether these people were able to
provide with
sufficient income was doubtful. Increased migration led to a
significant drop
in the country’s population, including in the rural areas (11).
In 2001-2002 the government adopted
two-level grain purchasing scheme. In accordance with the Law ”On
Agricultural
Corporation and their Associations” (December of 2000)
the
Agricultural Corporation was established. This corporation is 100 %
owned by the
state and is able to mandate the establishment of credit partnerships
in rural
areas. During this period the government made a number of key decisions
such as
ensuring lower prices for fuel, providing subsidies for seed-farming,
livestock
breeding, crop protection and veterinary programs (11).
In 2002 the state allocated 15,6
billion tenge for agriculture, a figure which was 1,5 billion tenge
more than
in 2001. The state portfolio of agricultural loans grew up to 12,3
billion
tenge in 2002 compared with 8,42 million tenge in 2001.
Positive changes appeared in the rural social
sector and the number of
rural settlement without a medical care facility or attendant dropped
during
2001. In the same year 70 first aid centres were re-opened, as well as
17
medical-obstetric centres and 27 rural hospitals. But, the quality of
medical
care and the resource base of rural medical centres still leave much to
be
desired. Similar problems remain in rural education and the same
measures have
been taken by the state in education and in other area of rural sector
development (11). In 2001 new secondary
schools were built in the rural area, which provided additional
12 799
places for school attendance. Regarding the pre-school institutions
only 162
additional place in rural were provided by authorities (2). Despite
that
economic development of a rural area remained the government priorities
the
President announced the National Rural Development Program for 2004-
2010 under
which the sufficient funds are supposed to allocate for creation of a
social
infrastructure in the selected rural areas.
2.3
Rural
Economy and Poverty.
Kazakhstan’s population in 2002 was 14.82
million, of which 43.4 percent was located in rural areas.
The relative proportion of rural and urban
populations has not changed significantly since 1989 (2). Although a
total of
approximately 600,000 rural inhabitants have moved to urban areas
between 1995-
2002. However, the shift in
population
from rural to urban areas has been relatively balanced by emigration to
other
countries from urban areas. In general, the migration process has been
characterized by the following pattern: Kazakh people migrate within
country
–mostly to regional centres such as Almaty and Astana cities; members
of other
ethnic group have tended to emigrate to their original countries such
as Russia, Germany and other countries (11).
Table 1: Total and rural
population
ear
|
1989
|
1995
|
2002
|
Total
|
16,1992
|
15,9567
|
14,8209
|
Rural
population
|
7,063
|
7,069
|
6,472
|
Rural
in percentage
|
43,60%
|
44,30%
|
43,67%
|
This data represents a decline in the rural
population of approximately 0,6 million people over the past decade
while the overall
population declined by 1,4 million of people. The overall rural
population
density is low, at less than 6 persons per square kilometre while the
rural
population density is very high in the southern regions. The rural
population
densities within most oblasts reflects on the resource endowments
within these
administrative units and the area with favourable climate conditions
for
agriculture it is much higher compared with to those areas with
unfavourable
conditions.
At the end of 2003, 30.9
percent of Kazakhstan’s rural population had an income
below the minimum monthly subsistence level of 5162 KZT
(approximately$35.00). Rural
poverty is a significant issue in Kazakhstan and the Government of Kazakhstan
has taken two related approaches to address this challenge. The first is to focus on issues, which are
specific
to the rural sector, such as the provision of physical infrastructure,
health
and education, and measures to improve the viability of the local
economies,
etc. A significant number of farms are
unprofitable however more resources will be directed to those rural
settlements
that are considered to have stronger economic potential. This is both
to
maximize the return on the Government’s investment and to encourage
migration
from those settlements with less potential. The second and related
approach is
focused on the agricultural industry, which accounts for an estimated
90
percent of rural economic activity (6).
Table 2
: Poverty Distribution by Oblast, 2003
|
Total
|
Urban
|
Rural
|
Akmola
|
16.4
|
10.9
|
20.6
|
Aktobe
|
19.0
|
6.8
|
35.5
|
Almaty
|
25.3
|
10.5
|
31.5
|
Atyray
|
32.7
|
25.5
|
44.0
|
West Kazakhstan
|
17.1
|
7.0
|
23.9
|
Zhambyl
|
30.0
|
21.0
|
36.6
|
Karaganda
|
15.1
|
9.0
|
40.1
|
Kostanai
|
21.0
|
9.2
|
34.3
|
Kyzyl-Orda
|
27.1
|
17.9
|
42.2
|
Mangistau
|
26.0
|
19.1
|
59.9
|
North Kazakhstan
|
26.1
|
19.2
|
29.8
|
Pavlodar
|
17.1
|
7.1
|
32.8
|
South Kazakhstan
|
11.9
|
3.8
|
17.0
|
East Kazakhstan
|
16.9
|
10.1
|
26.8
|
Astana
city
|
2.1
|
2.1
|
-
|
Almaty
city
|
3.9
|
3.9
|
-
|
Kazakhstan
|
19.8
|
10.8
|
30.9
|
This table shows the highest proportions of
population with income below the living minimum subsistence level are
seen in
Mangistau (59.9 %), Atyray (44 %),
Kyzyl-Orda (42,2 %) and Aktobe (35,5%).
These oblasts are regions with huge oil deposits and the economy of
these
regions has substantial growth and is one of the main contributors to
the GDP
of the country. Thus, impressive economic results do not always lead to
improvement in the conditions of the poor in rural areas.
Wages in
agriculture have always been lower than industry, but the gap has never
been so
significant. For example, in 1985 and 1991 agricultural workers earned
89 % and
78 % of industrial workers respectively. By 1994 this had dropped to 37
% and
compared with nation’s average salary it was 60 %. This downward trend
in
agricultural versus industrial wages has persisted, falling to 28 % in
2001, or
only 39 % of average wages nation –wide. In the last three years wages
in
agriculture remained the low. In comparison with other wages in other
sectors
agricultural wages are one fifth of salaries in the finance sector or
slightly
over 30 % in the transportation and communication sector employees. The
above
ratios are true for all regions. Recently government policy prioritised
industry development and it has led to a serious deterioration in the
living
standards of rural population and caused the migration of significant
number of
the younger and working age population to the cities (11).
3. Implementation of
Land Reform
3.1. Land Reform Concept.
The Land Code of 2003 establishes two form of
land ownership for agricultural land –private land ownership and land
possession under temporary or permanent land use rights. In addition,
the Land
Code recognises equal protection for state and private land ownership.
This
Land Code provided the legal framework for land privatization and its
conversion into tradable commodities. The owner of land has the right
to
possess, to use and to dispose of their own land at their own
discretion and
will. The definition of “private ownership for land’ by Land Code is
the ability
to possess, to use and dispose of a land plot on the base, conditions
and
limits, established by land legislation. This definition complies with
the principle
of ownership within Roman Law and consequently with Kazakh civil
legislation.
The
legislation stipulates the following ways that private ownership for
land can
arise:
-
acquiring
a land plot on the basis of legal state acts through purchase of the
land
plot from the state;
-
acquisition
of land plot under deals, stipulated by civil legislation such as
purchase
from private land owners, donation and concession of ownership right;
-
acquiring a land plot via inheritance or the
re-organization of legal entities.
The purchase of a land plot for
private
ownership from the state could be made in the following ways: purchase
of a land
plot according to its cadastre value (assessed), acquisition of plot on
delayed
payment and at the reduced prices by lump sum or by delayed payment for
10
years. All those three methods should be based on the cadastre value of
land
plot.
The Land Code gives the priority for purchasing
state owned agricultural land to rural residents, who will conduct
farming by their
own actions and who have specific agricultural knowledge and experience
in
working with land plot. Citizens and legal entities have the right to
buy land at
the reduced prices in size of 75 percent of cadastre value, established
by
Government Resolution. In case of purchase of land for ten years the
land could
be used as collateral after 50 percent of the purchase price has been
paid with
only the repaid amount of land being pledged as collateral.
The Code also establishes the maximum size of
land plot that can be purchased, something which varies from region to
region.
The following limits of maximum size of land plot established: for the
citizen
of Kazakhstan – from 30 hectares up to 25 000 hectares, including
irrigated land – from 1 hectare up to 1400 hectares; for non-state
legal
entities and its affiliated entities- from
150 hectares up to 240 000 hectares
including irrigated land-
from 5 hectares up to 19 000 hectares.
Explicit criteria for determining of maximum
sizes of land plot were not incorporated in the land legislation. Most
probably
the government established the maximum size of a land plot on the basis
of
prevailing peasant farms size in the regions.
The land
legislation establishes the permanent use rights for state legal
entities and
temporary land use rights for non-state legal entities, citizens and
international organizations. The land use right is the ability to
possess use and
secure benefits in various forms on the basis of the lease contract. The granting of land use rights to legal
entities and citizens is decided by the local executive body. Land use
right can
arise in the following ways:
-
acquiring
land plot by leasing land directly from the state;
- acquiring land by concluding lease contract
with private owners of land plots;
- acquiring land use rights through universal
assignments
such as inheritance or the re-organization
of legal entities.
In
accordance with Land Code the land use could be:
- temporary
land use on paid
basis, which might be:
- short-term up to 5 years;
- long-term up to 49 years.
- temporary
land use on non-paid basis not exceeding 5 year as land plot for civil
servant
and employees of state enterprises, determined by Government Resolution;
- permanent
land use, granted to needs of
state landusers.
3.2. Procedure of Land
Allocation and Entitlement.
The Land
Code specifies the procedure for land allocation both for private
ownership and
under temporary land use right for 49 years. In both cases, those
interested
must submit their application to
local
executive body with their application, containing the following
information:
-
purpose of land plot use;
-
proposed size of land plot ;
-
location of land plot;
-
requested type of land ownership;
-
presence
of other land plot, granted to private ownership without payment.
The application should be considered within
three
months from time of actual acceptance of the application. By the order
of the
local executive body the regional Agency for Land Resources Management
should determine
whether the request is in conformity
with territorial
zoning and should organize the preliminary search for a suitable land
plot. Then
the proposal should be considered by the committee, which could be
created by the
local executive body and made up of local deputies, representatives of Agency for Land
Resources Management and other state agencies and persons, appointed by
the executive
local body.
The decision concerning the land plot should be
sent to the applicant during seven days after the decision has been
made. Any refusal
to grant land must be supported by full and written reasons. Following
a decision
to grant land the regional Agency for Land Resources Management should
prepare
the contact for land purchase and receive payment. This contract for
land
purchase should become the official basis for issuing the legal
documents and
be accepted as proving the land right.
The physical identification of the land plot
shall
be implemented by specialised legal entities and citizens, who are
licensed to
carry out such work. The work on physical identification of land plot
comprises
the initial elaboration of the land plot scheme and a strict definition
of the
land plot with demarcated border and other land attributes and finally
execution
of the project with all attendant documentation. The use of land before
the defining
of the land plot is not permitted and violation of this provision is
subject to
administrative remedies.
The legal documents, that establish land use
right are provided by the state Agency for Land Resources Management.
These
documents together with the land project, prepared by specialised legal
entities, should be presented to the regional state agency for
registration of
real estate and deals. After checking all documents, proving the land
use right
this agency shall register private ownership right. In accordance with
current
registration, any rights on the property and other ownership should be
registered and will come into force after this registration. Thus, the
land use
right will be certified by legal act in the form of a deed, which
should be registered.
In addition, this agency records all other encumbrances on the land
such as
mortgage, leases and other restrictions, thereby showing
complete inventory of legal rights on the
land.
The Land Code provides provisions for acquiring
land into the private ownership in cases where it is currently used for
agricultural production under temporary land use right. In this case,
the
applicant should submit additional documents, such as the dead of
temporary
land use right, a copy of business registration certificate, inquiry
from tax
inspectorate on absence of debts, inquiry from the centre for
registration of
real estate and deals. The regional land state committee should
identify the
land plot, determine the cadastre (assessed) value of land and prepare
the
draft of decision about granting private ownership on land plot. This decision should be made within one month
period from the date of applying.
The granting of land plot for private ownership
or under temporary land use right for the creation of peasant farm is
considered in this Land Code. In addition to the documents listed
previously the
applicant should also submit a brief program of the proposed farming,
documents, proving the work experience of the peasant farm head in
agricultural
production and relevant agricultural education, copy of taxpayer
certificate
and address of the head of peasant farm. The document, proving the
right to the
land plot should be given to the head of the peasant farm with a list
of names
of all the member of the peasant farm.
The Land Code also provides an opportunity to
receive
land plot for private ownership or temporary land use right, when it is
currently occupied by agricultural entities under lease contract. The
application of citizen concerning the withdrawal of land under use by
an agricultural
enterprise should be submitted to this agricultural enterprise and
considered
within one month if the citizen applied before sowing or after the
completing
harvesting. In some cases receiving a land plot from the agricultural
enterprise will only be possible with the consent of the agricultural
enterprise. Thus, legislation defends the right of the agricultural
producer to
refuse to cede land plot, which was sowed by them. The legislation does
not
guarantee the right of citizens to land from the agricultural
enterprise and
there are no particular provisions to ensure that plot applicant are
given good
plots of land. Even if these applicants
are and share holders they do not have any right for certain plots of
land plot
because their land shares do not specify the location of land plot, but
only
their size.
The local executive body does not consider such
application and thus decisions to grant land should be made on the
basis of
land location project and with the consent of agricultural enterprises.
All
disputes arising may be considered by the court. However, these appeals
to
court do have their own limitations. Court procedures are costly and
take significant
amounts of time before a decision is made. Court trials are not the
best solution
for citizens, wishing to get land plot from agricultural enterprise.
The Land Code contains some provisions, which
secure the right of members, who possess the land plot under “joint
ownership”,
which means possession of land by two or several owners. Such members
have the
right to exit the collective with a physical land plot, corresponding
to the
individual share of collective property. It will not be possible in
cases when the
land plot is not divisible and the person, who exits the collective can
sell
their land share to outside people. But before doing this he/she should
notify
the other members of the collective in writing concerning this deal and
those
people have priority on purchasing this land share. Division of land
plot under
collective ownership should be made after a preliminary decision
determining
the land share of each member. The provisions of Land Code establishes
a
mechanism for transferring land from joint ownership to private and
guarantees
the individual’s freedom of choice. In
such a way, individuals are entitled to leave the collective taking
their share
of land with them.
3.3. Restrictions
on the
Rights of Landowners and Landusers.
The Land
Code establishes the following basis for termination of land ownership
or land
use right:
-
alienation
of land plot or use right by another entities;
-
voluntary
refusal of landowner from their private ownership or landusers from
their land use right;
- deprivation
of ownership and land use right in
accordance with existing legislation.
Ownership
rights and land use right can also be withdrawn by following cases:
- presence of claim from creditors;
- compulsory
purchase for state needs;
- deterioration
of land and environment and use of land
for not specified
purpose ;
- when
land has been subject to radioactive pollution;
- confiscation
by the decision of the court on
criminal offences.
Land use rights could
also be terminated by the expiry of a term of granting land plot or
lease
contract.
The Land Code regulates
land use and land relations in order to further the rational and
effective use
of land and also, because the land is considered a natural resources
rather
than simply an asset. The
Code gives priority to land protection as a necessary component for the
safe
use of land in agricultural production. The owners of land plot can
possess,
use and freely dispose with land plots, but their rights can be
terminated by
non-sanctioned changes of use or following infringements, which cause,
damage
and deterioration in the quality of land. In such cases, the regional
Agency
for Land Resources Management brings a suit to court and the decision
to withdraw
land will be made by the court. Landowners have the right to defend
their right
in court.
The Land Code intends to defend the public
interest in land relations. A number of provisions provide individuals
and
legal entities with opportunities to own a land plot. However, the Land
Code also
restricts the rights of owner in case of conflict with public interest. Land can be withdrawn from private hands by
means of compulsory purchase in the following cases: to meet
international
commitments; for needs of defence, park zone or recreational centre;
where minerals
are found under the land; for the construction of roads, infrastructure
building
and related installation.
In accordance with the Land Code in these cases
the state should buy the land at a price, agreed with the owner of the
land
plot. If the owner refuses to sell their land plot at a reasonable
price, the local
executive body has the right to bring a suit to court regarding the
purchase price.
Land legislation gives priority to the local executive body rather than
the land
owners when it comes to determining the price for the plot sought for
public
needs.
The Land Code establishes certain restrictions
on the acquisition of land plot into ownership in particular foreign
citizens
and entities are not permitted to buy either land of agricultural value
and
non-agricultural land. The land legislation does allow foreign citizens
and
person without citizenship to receive a land plot of agricultural value
under temporary
land use rights for 10 years.
In accordance with Government Resolution
citizens
and legal entities have the right to buy land at 75 percent of cadastre
value.
But in this case the new owner will not able to make any deals normally
allowed
by civil legislation for a period of 10 years. These owners can only
pledge their
land plot as collateral. The same restriction applies to owners of
land, who
bought land plot on a delayed payment for 10 years either at the basic
price or
reduced prices. As regards pledging as collateral they have right to
pledge both
as collateral after repayment of 50 percent of land cadastre value and
only on the
repaid amounts in both cases. The landowners are also restricted from
any deals
with their land except using it as collateral unless they repurchase
the land
use right from the state.
3.4. Restrictions to Land
Shares Owners.
The previous land legislation envisaged that
some
land shares will be given for lease to legal entities and peasant farms
and
consequently land plots, which were intended to allocate among the
owners of
land share would be cultivated by leasehold owners. According to the
Agency on Land
Resources Management of 1, January 2004 about 628.6 thousands land
shares were given
to legal entities and peasant farms under lease contract, covering a
total area
of 26.3 million hectares. Approximately 60 percent of these land shares
are located
in northern regions, where the cereal productions prevail due to the
climatic
conditions (7).
In order to ensure a prompt
transition to private
ownership for agricultural land the Land Code contains Transitional
Provisions,
which had the effect of imposing certain restrictions on land shares
and land
use rights. These provisions are as follows:
- citizens
of Kazakhstan and non-state legal entities who lease their land
plot to secondary users are obliged to
cancel
these lease contract (sub-lease) by 1st January 2005;
- holders
of land shares, who lease their land shares for lease are obliged
to realize their rights until 1, January of
2005 on term and conditions established by
legislation.
The
owners of land shares hold the rights for realization of their rights
under
this Land Code. In particular,
the right for a land share must be realised by one of the following
methods:
-
purchase of
the land plot for private ownership;
- acquiring
the land plot for joint or individual land use for farming or
agricultural production;
- transfer by means
of a contribution to the statutory
fund of partnership or other legal entities.
Granting land by
land shares is
made under the general
procedures of land allocation. Once land ownership or land use right
has been
granted previous contracts such as lease contract for the land plot or
lease
contract for a land share are considered repealed.
If the owners of the land
shares do not fulfil
one of listed options for realizing their rights they will forfeit the
right to
a land share and the “virtual land” will be transferred to a special
local land
fund by decision of the local executive body.
Citizens
and non-state legal entities, who possess the land plot under temporary
land
use right, have the following right to:
- purchase
of the land plot for private ownership;
- acquiring
the land plot for joint or individual land use for farming or
agricultural production;
- transfer
by means of a contribution to the statutory fund of partnership or other legal
entities.
If the landuser does not fulfil one of listed
options for realising their rights under land tenure the cancellation
of the sub-lease
contract and the termination of temporary land use right will be
ordered by of
a court procedure following application by the regional Agency for Land
Resources Management. Following such a decision their land plot will be
transferred to special local land fund by the decision of a court.
The owners of land shares may transfer these to
farming entities by creating an informal partnership on the basis of a
contract
of joint business activity. In the first stage, the owners of land
share must
submit their application to the legal entity, where they have decided
to place their
land shares.
In the second stage the legal entities must
make a decision to change their charter because of the appearance of
new
participants. The decision to change a charter must be taken by
authorised
bodies such as the general meeting of member of the production
cooperative,
general meeting of participants in the partnership or for joint stock
companies
a general meeting of shareholders. On the decision of these authorised
bodies
the business entities must prepare the relevant legal documents and
identify
the participation of new members in their business. In case of
partnership the
additional contract must be signed by both parts. In all business
entities
amendments to their charter must be made and it should reflect changes
in the numbers
of participants.
In the third stage an evaluation of these land
shares ought to be performed by an assessment of auditors or by
agreement
between the parts. The Land Code does
not specify exactly how the assessment of land share could be made. The
manual
on Land Code, prepared by the Research Centre under Presidential
Administration
only recommended some procedure for evaluating land shares.
In the fourth stage the land project of these
business entities should be checked by the state Agency for Land
Resources
Management. The executive state body will make a decision regarding the
granting of the land plot to this business entity.
Then land plot will be physically allocated
and all State Acts (deeds) for land use will be given to this business
entity.
Finally, registration of this business entity
should be made in oblast branches of Ministry of Justice. The share
issuance must
be made for joint stock companies.
3.5. Land Payment
Despite the fact that agricultural land was
given to farmers for temporary land use without any payment, the land
plots under
temporary land use are subject to land tax in accordance with the Tax
Code. The
Tax Code (12th, June 2001) establishes two tables of tax
rates based
on the variability of land quality across the regions. The first table
is
relevant to land on the steppe and dry steppe with usual and southern
chernozem, chestnut and dark-chestnut soil and piedmont area with
chernozem,
dark gray soil and chestnut. The second table covers all other types of
land,
including semi-desert, desert and dry piedmont areas with all type of
soils in
those areas. The range within the first table, containing the more
favourable lands
for agriculture varies between 0,48 tenge per 1 hectare for the lowest
quality
of land to 202,65 tenge per hectar for the
highest quality of land soil. Tax rates for the majority of lands for
agricultural production are within a tax range of 14 tenge and 34 tenge
per
hectare. The range of the second table varies between 0,48 tenge per 1
hectare for the lowest quality of land
and 50,18 tenge per hectare for the highest quality soil.
This land payment applies to land plot, which
have
been allocated for temporary use under lease. Lease payments are linked
to land
taxes and the annual lease rate is determined by Resolution of
Government (No
890, 2, September of 2003) within the range of 100-120 percent of basic
rate of
tax payment for land. The size, condition and the schedule of payment
of the lease
contract is determined within the actual contract, but the size of the
lease
payment should not exceed this established range.
The cadastre value is determined by the regional
state Agency for Land Resources Managements on the basis of base
payment rates
for land plots. They were established by a Resolution of Government of
Republic
of Kazakhstan (No 890, 2nd, September, 2003) and depend on the type of
farmland
and the actual regional location. The base rates of payment for land
are
established per hectare and differentiated by type of land soil.
The basic rates of payment for
land vary in the
following ranges at the current exchange rate 130 tenge to 1 USD as of
1.06.05:
- arable land - between 60 USD and 428 USD;
- irrigated
land - between 244
USD and 1572 USD;
- hay
field - between 24 USD and 139 USD;
- pasture –
between 13 USD and 98 USD.
3.7. Deficiencies Identified
in the Land Code.
The land legislation being a comprehensive set
of legal and normative acts, embracing all aspects of land relations,
has some
disputable provisions. One such provision, which provokes disputes and
disagreements among politicians and land specialists, is the
regulation, cancelling
sub-lease agreements. A second disputed provision concerns the owners
of land
shares who according to the relevant provisions have to make a decision
on
their land share. In both cases the last date is 1 January
2005.
The land reform is one complicated part of
agrarian reform and it usually takes a significant amount of time to
implement a
new law and many factors determine the speed of land reform. The Land
code
itself is a whole legal framework with complicated institutional and
financial
aspects that themselves exert a significant influence over the progress
of land
reforms. Social and historical factors are also a key issue and land
reforms in Kazakhstan have proved this the case. When the legislators
introduce the next legislative acts in the form of laws and
presidential
decrees the peasants could not response immediately. It takes time for
the
rural population to make adequate decisions and act on the proposal and
regulation, established by land legislations. For example, the result
of the land
reforms proposed by the Law “ On Land ”
of 1995 only became visible and achievable in 2001 yet the result of
this
reform was soon cancelled out by the
introduction
of the new Law ”On land” in 2001.
In this current proposed schedule it is obvious
that many peasants will try to make a decision concerning their land or
land
shares . However, it is likely that not all of them will be able to
implement
all the necessary steps that will entitle them to the land rights.
Despite the Land
Code being promulgated on June 2003 it was not possible to implement
the land
reform, because the Land Code did not contain guidelines concerning the
procedures
for introducing these changes. The
relevant
provisions of the Land Code could be applied after the issuing of the
Manual on
Land Reform on March 2004 b y the Research Centre under Presidential
Administration. The result was that peasants have less than 9 months to
conduct
all the legal procedures, stipulated in the land and civil legislation.
Only a couple farms were able to re-register by
the end of March of 2004 as required by current legislation in Atbasar
raion of
Akmola oblast, which was a project area for conducting social and
economic
survey for this research. By the beginning of October only several
farms of
this raion have re-registered and the majority of farms in this rayon
are at the
stage of performing the legal procedures for re-registering their
farms.
Nevertheless, these farms were able to meet the dead line of 1st January
2005.
According to official
statistics the
contribution of 628.6 thousands land shares (reported as of 1 of
January 2004)
was made by the land owners in the following ways:
-
contributed to the statutory fund of partnerships
-44,6 percent;
-
contributed to statutory fund of peasants farms
-
23,2 percent;
- used
for organizing agricultural production
-
17,2 percent.
-
contributed to production cooperative
- 4 percent
- unused
or refused land shares
-
9,7 percent.
The latter figure revokes some
concern because
this official statistics does not provide any breakdown by more
detailed
explanation of this category. This figure shows that more 60 thousands
of rural
residents were not able to realize their right, which was given by land
share.
It might some rural residents, who were not able to manage on time with
their
land shares, in some extend it might be some so- called “morally
degrading”
people some kind of vulnerable group of people, who does not take any
cares about
own. Most likely some farms missed to meet the
deadline for official re-registration and peasants
in some remote areas with severe
conditions for crop growing had no opportunity to contribute their land
shares
to a farming business, because of the absence such entities. Currently,
it is
very difficult to believe to Kazakh statistics now, particularly on
some
sensitive issues such land relations, even this published data does not
give
100 percent in total (miss of 1,3 percent). In case of Atabasar raion
this data
on percentage of unused or refused land shares might be true, because
the local
branch of Agency for Land Resources Management was headed by qualified
specialist
in land relations and the region was attractive for crop growing. And it is very difficult to imagine the
situation in others regions, where crop growing is very risky due to
climatic
conditions.
Another critical point might be the cancellation
of secondary land leases, which will considerably limit the freedom of
landusers. The tenants on such land plots must start farming otherwise
they will
lose their right to the land. This provision goes against with the
civil law
principle of freedom of entrepreneurial activities. A fairer
alternative would
be to allow sub-lease for secondary landuser for terms less than their
principal agreement with the state.
At the initial stages of agricultural land
market development the lease could be serve as an alternative means for
transferring
land from less to more productive producers. In the experience of other
countries encouraging of land rental markets coincides with measures to
reduce
the credit and insurance market imperfection in rural areas. The high
risk in
agricultural production in rural Kazakhstan means that the development of both
these markets is hampered. Alongside increasing the productivity of
agricultural production leasing land could be cautious step for tenant
farmers
to start business.
The majority of agricultural land remains in the
possession of non-state agricultural enterprises. These entities rent
land from
the owners of land shares and therefore these entities possess a
considerable
part of the agricultural land, which accounts for several thousands
hectares of
agricultural land in northern regions, favourable for cereal
productions. The
Land Code aims to prevent such concentration of agricultural land in
the hand
of single owner or legal entity by establishment the maximum size of
land plot
in each raions. Some owners of
enterprises or legal entities have land in possession in various
regions. The
Land Code does not regulate whether legal entities or individuals can
own land
in different raions. Also, the definition of “affiliated legal
entities” is not
introduced in the Land Code. Thus the
introduced provision on maximum size of land plot does not prevent from
the
concentration of land areas in hand of certain businesses or
individuals.
A certain concern exists around the delegation
of so much power to local executive bodies, particular in the
allocation of
land to citizens and legal entities. In Kazakhstan, the process of state governance
and local management is not transparent and as a result the local
executive
bodies, having powers in local management, may make a decision
according to its
own discretion. The Land Code gives the right to local executive body
the right
in land allocation and yet the legislation does not stipulate the
grounds on
which an application might be refused and the land legislation only
requires
that any refusal must be justified. The actual process of land plot
allocation
is important as lands in good condition and in appropriate locations
are always
in demand. An applicant may find that he
or she is refused land tenure in the requested place due to reluctance
of local
executive body to allocate this land plot. Moreover, land legislation
does not
provide any criteria for ranking applicants and it provides that the
process of
land granting became non-transparent.
Another issue that was omitted in this Land
Code is that the evaluation of land share is hampered by the absence of
real
market value of agricultural land. The recommendation of the Research
Centre under
Presidential Administration is based on a finding that the share of
land use
rights in business entities is about 20-25 percent of the statutory
fund and
they stated that in the majority of cases it is between 5-10 percent.
This
assumption is incorrect, because required capital for establishment of
a
partnership or other legal entities is considerable less than cost of
land use
rights, established by land legislation. As an example, the Research
Centre
suggested that the share of land shares should be 20 percent of total
statutory
fund of partnership, because in these cases the owners of land share
should
receive dividends at one fifth the net profit of business. All these
assumption
do not have much economic realities, because the cost of land use
rights is significant
in comparison with the actual assets of farm. But at the same time, the
land
legislation does not determine the cost of the land shares nor describe
the
procedure for land share evaluation.
The majority of those, who organized farms, who
made own cash contribution to business, secured financing from banks
and inputs
from supplier, who carried all the entrepreneurial risks associated
with
farming do not agree with the idea of comparing cost of land use rights
to the
value of the farm assets. As example, one interviewed head of farm in
neighbouring raion of the same oblast told me that he removed from
urban area
to one village and took the land under land use rights. The residents
of this
village had one option to rent out their shares to single farm, which
was not
profitable. This entrepreneur was able to organize sustainable farm and
provide
the rural residents with paid in cash work. He completely disagrees
that the
land share will take a significant share in his business.
Thus, such entrepreneurs were able to get the
significant share in their business to compare with share of all other
participants with their land shares. This issue of appraising the value
of land
share is pending with no criterion even suggested by the legislators.
It is difficult to determine the market value
of land in the absence of a land market for arable land. After
introducing private
ownership on agricultural land no transaction occurred in the raion,
where the
research and the survey were conducted. It is most likely a similarly
situation
in other raions in the northern regions. The lack of any legally
established
procedure for determining market value of land and land shares allows
the
dominant agricultural entities to determine the value of land shares by
their
discretions which means at lowest cost. The value of land shares varies
from 89
tenge up to 23 852 tenge and the size of land share and quality of
soil
are the same. It emphasize that a fair
appraisal
of land share is needed, because appraisal by agreement by parts is not
always
fair and it does not correspond to the economic costs of a land share.
4. Social and Economic
Analysis of Rural Area.
4.1. Demographic
Profile of Rural Residents.
The average size of a rural family in the
country is about 4, 4 persons and approximately 48 percent of all
families
consist of between four and five persons (12). Small families with one
or two
persons, which are basically families without children and families of
elderly
people over 60 years of age, account for 31 percent. This is
significantly
higher than the number of households with three persons, which accounts
for 20
percent. The families with four and five and more persons amount for 22
percent
and 26 percent, respectively (2). This data shows that the demographic
profile
of rural areas has significant number of rural households with small
number of
family member, which is about 51 percent. The main reason for such a
demographic structure is out migration by young people from rural area
to
cities and urban areas.
Most family members are adults (58,3 %) of
normal working age, which is between the age of 19 and 60, youth under
the age
of 19 account for 31,4 percent of family members and elderly people
account for
10,3 percent in the country as of 1st January
2002 . The proportion of households with
one and two
children accounts for 45
and 34 percent relatively while households with three and four children
account
for 14 and 7 percent, respectively. In other words this data shows that
the majority
of rural families have one or two children (2).
The number of male and female in the rural
population
is approximately equal - 49, 9 percent is male and rest female. The
head of
household is male in 61 % of cases and female in 39 % of cases. Women
are
reported as head of household where families are without males or males
of
normal working age and where other males are either minors or seniors
(12).
Among adults of normal working age, a
considerable
number of these are employed by the local farm enterprise. The
percentage of males
employed is considerably higher than the percentage of females employed
on the
farm. The main occupations of females who work in the village are
social
services, teachers, medical personnel or staff of the local
administration. In
rare cases, agricultural farms employ the females on their ancillary
production
facilities. The official statistic of employment concerning agriculture
looks very
unrealistic, reporting that the rate of employment account for 92,6
percent in
rural areas in Kazakhstan (3). A certain
number of males in the rural areas are
engaged in agricultural production on a permanent basis, but not all of
them.
And only a small number of females are involved in any employment. The
high
rate of employment most likely comes from the way of official reporting
that
considers the unemployed rural people as a category of people engaged
in self- production
activities. The presence of cattle or a subsidiary land plot is a
crucial factor
for considering them as employed workers.
4. 2.Comparative
Analysis of Households Income.
The size of the household budget varies
according
to the number of adults, but it is more affected by the status of
adults. Highest
earning usually are found in families where both adults have employment
in
state organisations whereas the lowest level of income is relevant to
pensions
and families, where the adults do not have permanent employment. The
structure
of income according to the main categories of household is presented in
the following
table.
ncome items
|
Budget of local servants
|
Budget of pensioners
|
Budget of employed workers by farms
|
Budget of unemployed on permanent base
|
Income from land plot
|
12
500
|
4,7%
|
6
500
|
3,9%
|
12
500
|
5,3%
|
18
500
|
13,3%
|
Livestock product
|
30
000
|
11,3%
|
5
000
|
3,0%
|
35
000
|
14,9%
|
75
000
|
53,8%
|
Salary
|
204
000
|
76,8%
|
|
|
168
000
|
71,6%
|
|
|
Pensions
|
|
|
134
400
|
81,5%
|
|
|
|
|
Income from lease of share
|
19
000
|
7,2%
|
19
000
|
11,5%
|
19
000
|
8,1%
|
19
000
|
13,6%
|
Other income
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
27
000
|
19,4%
|
Total
|
265
500
|
100%
|
164
900
|
100%
|
234
500
|
100%
|
139
500
|
100%
|
It should be noted that
employment in the local
state organizations provides the family with a 21 percent higher income
than
employment in agricultural farms and pensioners get approximately 18
percent
more income compared with those rural people, who do not have permanent
employment.
4.3. Budget of Rural
Households.
The structure of the average household budget
for 2003 in Atbasar rayon, where the survey was conducted, is shown
below.
Household annual budget for 2003
No
|
Items
|
in tenge
|
In USD
|
in percentage
|
|
Revenue
|
|
|
|
1
|
Income
from land plot
|
12 500
|
89,3
|
6%
|
2
|
Income
from sales of livestock products
|
36 250
|
258,9
|
18,0%
|
3
|
Salary
from employment
|
93 000
|
664,3
|
46,2%
|
4
|
Pensions
|
33 600
|
240,0
|
16,7%
|
5
|
Rent
payments
|
19 000
|
135,7
|
9,4%
|
6
|
other
income, including temporary employment
|
6 750
|
48,2
|
3,4%
|
|
Total
|
201 100
|
1 436,4
|
100%
|
|
Expenditures
|
|
|
|
1
|
Expenses
for crop growing
|
1 200
|
9
|
0,6%
|
2
|
Expenses
for cattle breeding
|
14 000
|
100
|
7,0%
|
3
|
Utilities
|
34 000
|
243
|
16,9%
|
4
|
Food
|
104 500
|
746
|
52,0%
|
5
|
Clothes
|
37 700
|
269
|
18,7%
|
6
|
Expenses
on children education
|
2 000
|
14
|
1,0%
|
7
|
Consumer
goods
|
2 500
|
18
|
1,2%
|
8
|
Purchase
of cattle
|
0
|
0
|
0,0%
|
9
|
Purchase
of other means of production
|
0
|
0
|
0,0%
|
10
|
Taxes
|
500
|
4
|
0,2%
|
11
|
Other
expenses
|
900
|
6
|
0,4%
|
|
Total expenses
|
197 300
|
1 409
|
98,1%
|
|
Deficit or surplus
of budget
|
3 800
|
27
|
|
The average household income in the sample is
about 1430 USD in 2003 and the family derive its income mainly from
wages, their
household plots and rent payments. Some households have additional
income from the
sales of cattle and other animals. The wage income and the sales of
meat are
primarily cash while the rent payments usually are paid in kind. The
output
from the household plot output is consumed by them as foodstuffs,
because the
household plot is mainly used for growing potatoes, vegetables.
The salary is considered as the main source of
farms
income and it accounts for nearly 46, 2 percent of their total income.
The share
of income from the sales of livestock products and pensions is about 18
percent
and 17 percent, respectively. The income
from lease payments accounts for less than 10 percent of the total
household
income. The main products, which received as payment in kind, are
grain, animal
feed, hay, flour and bread, but the rural residents prefer to get
animal feed,
hay and forage as payment in kind in order to feed their household
cattle,
sheep and other animals.
The largest items of
household expenditure are the expenses for food, clothes and utilities
and they
account for 52 percent, 18,7 percent and 16,9 percent of total
household income
respectively. The food expenses comprise
the cash and non-cash expenses, which
is mainly livestock product and vegetables from a subsidiary land plot. The category of utility items includes the
expenses
for electricity and the purchase of coal, wood for heating their house
during
cold periods. Only employed workers and civil servants can afford to
pay for the
education of their children and the purchase of consumer goods and on
average
these amounts are small.
Expenses for cattle breeding and vegetable growing are mainly non-cash
expenses, which are made in kind and rarely, rural people can afford to
buy
seeds for vegetables to grow on their subsidiary land plot.
The average household
budget shows saving to the amount of 3800 tenge (approximately 27 USD
at rate
of 2003 end). The level of actual spending is 98,1 percent of the total income and it emphasises that the rural
residents
have only small amounts of saving and they spend almost all their
incomes in
order to cover the basic needs for food, clothes and appropriate living
conditions. The families with higher incomes can afford to make
expenses for
education of their children and purchase of consumer goods, but the
number of
such households is insignificant. In this regard rural residents have
only
little savings, because they need spend most of their incomes on
consumption.
4.4. Identified
Social
and Economic Problems in Rural Area.
The conducted survey in Atabasar raion of
Akmola oblast, in an area of cereal production, is an attempt to assess
the recent
significant changes in rural life and to investigate the scale of
problems
faced by the rural residents in the period of political and economic
changes in Kazakhstan. This survey is aimed to assess the economic
and social problems in rural areas based on people’s perception and
expert
opinions. The sociological survey of rural raions, conducted by UNDP in
2002 identified
several serious issues such as environmental problems (37 % of
respondents),
limited prospects for youth (41 %), access to drinking water (59,2 %),
the poor
status of roads (70,3 %) and unemployment (83 %) (12). Except for the
poor
status of roads these abovementioned problems were all expressed by
rural
residents during this survey. The roads in this area are in a good
condition
compared with other rural raions of Kazakhstan and the problem with drinking water
was mentioned in the survey by residents of one village in the Atbasar
raion.
The methodology of the survey was based on the
principle
of random selection. According to this
principle each tenth rural resident was interviewed by interviewers in
two
different counties. Rural residents of various ages, occupations and
professions,
responded to the questions. Some questions received very similar
answers and
others were answered differently by the respondents. In general, the
answers of
interviewed rural residents allow some conclusion to be made concerning
social
and economic issues in the rural areas and identifying the problems
faced by rural
residents during the period of transformation of rural economy from the
Soviet
system to the market economy.
The general profile of survey
respondents is the
following:
-
Men
make up 58 % of the survey respondents,
-
80 %
of the survey respondents are of working age, while 20 % are pensioners.
The
working age respondents consist of workers of private farms (48 %),
employee
of state financed local organizations (2 %), self-employed workers
(10 %) and unemployed respondent (20%).
-
All respondents hold a land share certificate.
In addition, the breakdown of survey
respondents by age group presented below:
Age
|
N =120
|
20-29
|
18 %
|
30-39
|
14 %
|
40-49
|
26 %
|
50-59
|
18 %
|
60-69
|
16 %
|
70 and older
|
8 %
|
The 40-49 year-old group contains the highest
percentage, followed by the 20-29 and 50-59 year old age groups. Some
survey
respondents in the 20-29 years-old group received land share
certificate as a bequest
from deceased relatives. All these respondents contributed their land
share
into the statutory fund of partnerships.
The UNDP sociological survey of rural areas
showed
that the rural residents incurred to poverty. This poverty situation in
rural Kazakhstan is conditioned by many factors:
economic recession, decline in real wages, increased unemployment
rates,
deteriorating social benefits, low income and increasing inequality.
According
to the survey of poor households “Causes and Conditions of Poverty in
Kazakhstan for 2002” conducted by the state statistical agency, the
main
reasons for poverty are the following: low wages (43,7% of
respondents),
inability to secure sustainable employment at the place of residence
(17 %), no
jobs at all (13%), lack of employment (7,5 %), presence of dependents
(5,4 %),
poor health status (4,1 %).
In the survey, conducted in Atbasar raion, the
respondents reported on question concerning well being in the following
ways.
Level of rural
residents well being.
|
Response of
survey respondents
|
Low
income not sufficient even for adequate nutrition
|
13,1%
|
Earned
income provides for food only with other basic needs being largely
unmet
|
14,8%
|
Earned
income provides for adequate nutrition, purchase of necessary clothes
and footwear but it is not enough to pay
for services
|
42,6%
|
Needs
of adequate nutrition, clothing footwear and buying services are met to
a certain extent
|
21,3%
|
Earned
income is enough for adequate nutrition, clothing footwear and buying
services and for purchase of some consumer goods.
|
8,2 %
|
No
financial problems
|
0
|
The result of the survey shows that about 15 %
of
rural respondents earn incomes that cover only their needs in food and
are not
enough to meet other needs. About 42
percent of rural respondent have incomes, which are enough for meeting
needs in
nutrition, clothing and footwear, but are not enough for paying for
services.
Only around one fifth of respondents are able to buy services to some
extent
and about 8 percent of respondents are able to buy some consumer goods.
Regarding the causes of poverty 74 % of
respondents reported that main causes of poverty are low salaries.
Other causes
of poverty are the following: absence of
permanent work (56 %), no jobs at all (16 %), poor health status (14%),
absence
of any social aids (36%), not enough educational background (8 %) and
unfavourable condition of living place such as poor economy of region
or environmental
problems (6%). Some respondents indicated two or three causes, but on
average
all respondent identified, at least two reasons of poverty. Respondents
of
working ages below 50 years old reported that the main cause of poverty
is low
salaries and the absence of permanent work and in some cases absence of
any
jobs. For female respondents and pensioners reported the main cause of
their
bad financial status is the absence of any social aids and poor health
status.
Correspondingly, the main factors that would,
according to respondents of working ages, improve their financial
status are
increased wages and permanent work (in both cases 78% of respondents).
Respondents were asked to select up to three possibilities that would
contribute
to improving their financial status. The third option for this group
varies from
the necessity of securing initial capital for opening own business (22
%), improving
the possibility to get credit (40%) to the importance of receiving a
land plot
into private ownership and land use right (10 %). The oldest
respondents reported
that main factors that would improve the financial status were
increased
pensions (24 %), improvement of medical care (32 %) and increase of
social aids
(20%).
Approximately half of respondents (48 %)
expressed the opinion that they would not foresee any changes in their
financial status and further one fifth of respondents believed that
their
financial status would improve only insignificantly.
Only a very small group of respondents (4%) is
optimistic, believing that their financial status would improve
significantly.
The remaining part of respondents (32 %) had difficulties in answering
this
question.
Regarding the expected ways of improving
financial
status the majority of respondents (90 % of respondents) stated that
they
believed in their own power, while the oldest respondents indicated
applied
that is improvement with the help of relatives and friends (42 % of
total
responses). Some of the youngest respondents believed that the deputies
and
heads of local executive bodies would help in improving their financial
status,
in both cases 6 % of responses.
The survey showed that the rural areas face
serious problems and future prosperity is not visible unless the
government
undertakes measures to ensure the economic development of the rural
areas.
Regarding the future perspectives of their villages the respondents
responded
differently and negatives responses prevailed in their answers.
Approximately, 31
percent and 40 percent of respondents reported that the number of rural
residents steadily would steadily decline and the village would not
have any
future perspectives respectively, while 27 percent of respondents
reported that
village did have the opportunity for development of agricultural
production.
Only 2 % of rural respondent believes that the future of their village
will be good
for rural residents.
The main problem for rural areas is out
migration
of rural residents. The main reasons for this are the absence of work
opportunities
in the rural areas (92 % of responses) together with the lack of money
for starting
their own business (64% of responses). Only a few respondents (4%)
indicated
that the unsatisfactory condition of school, medical establishment and
poor
services were the reasons for rural out migration.
Almost all residents
(94 % of respondents) consider the main obstacle to the development of
their
villages is the absence of initial funds for further growth of
agricultural
production. Only a few respondents (6 %) reported that the principal
obstacles
are remoteness from the main automobile roads, the low fertility of
land and
remoteness of markets for sales of agricultural commodities.
4.5. Attitude of Rural People to Private Land Ownership and Land
Shares.
The
survey was intended to get some idea regarding the perception of rural
residents on private ownership of agricultural land.
The survey showed that rural residents accept
the private ownership for agricultural land with two thirds of
respondents
expressing a positive attitude towards private ownership. Only 16 % of
respondent responded negatively towards the introduction of private
ownership,
while another 18 % of respondents had difficulties in answering this
question.
It is necessary to note that when the respondents were asked about what
type of
land tenure should be used for agricultural land only 26 % of
respondents stated
that private land ownership with the right to sale was appropriate.
More than
half of respondents (58 %) stated that ownership should be in the form
of lifetime
inheritable land tenure. Some respondents (12 % of respondents) had the
opinion
that agricultural land should remain under state ownership with 4 % of
respondents finding difficulties in answering this question.
Rural
residents were asked by the survey about their desire to receive a land
plot.
Two third expressed the desire to secure land tenure for land plot. Out
of
these respondents only one third stated that they would prefer to get
the land
tenure in the form of private land ownership whereas two thirds would
prefer to
receive use right for the land plot. About 33 % of respondents declared
that
they did not want a land plot. The most frequent explanations were old
age and
inability to work the land. In addition, those respondents, engaged in
employment with state bodies, stated they would not desire to get the
land
tenure.
All
those
respondents that were owners of a land shares were asked about the
obstacles to
securing land tenure for agricultural land. The respondents were
allowed to
indicate more than one reason. The vast majority (90 % of respondents)
stated
that the absence of money is the main obstacle to getting a land use
right or
purchasing land plot into private ownership. The other answers were
following:
lack of time and money for travel to raion and oblast centre
for getting a title for land (2 % of
responses); complicated procedure for getting land tenure (10% of
responses); unaware
of procedure for getting land tenure (12%).
Only 42
%
of respondents believe that the process of providing new titles for
land will
contribute to the growth of family welfare. Correspondingly, 4 % and 14
% of
respondents answered significantly and insignificantly improvement. Only 2% of respondents answered negatively
concerning
possible improvements in their family financial status while 36 % of
respondents had difficulties in answering the question. From this data
it might
be concluded that rural residents do consider land ownership as a means
improving
their financial status although the actual receipt of land for either
private
ownership or under use right will not provide substantial benefits.
The land
share owners are rural residents of various ages, social statuses and
professions, who are unable to enter independent farming and so who
look to rent
out their land shares to agricultural enterprises. The current
legislation
allows to owners of land shares to do this. The respondents were asked
their
opinion concerning the importance of lease contract for family income.
The
survey showed that many rural respondents (56 %) expressed their
dissatisfaction with the term and conditions of their lease contract
for land
shares. Less than half of respondents (40 %) stated that they consider
the
lease payment as important source of family income and while 4 percent
of
respondent had difficulties in answering.
The
survey asked the respondents about the importance of lease payments
compared
with total incomes. The result was that (56%) stated that income from
the land
share lease is less than 10 percent of the total family income. For
another group
of respondent (34 %) income from land share lease account for 10
percent of
total income whilst 10 percent stated that lease payments are equal to
15
percent of the total family income.
Another
way to assess the income from leases is to ask whether lessees are
fulfilling
their obligations to pay for lease in the amounts agreed and to pay on
time.
The majority of respondents (92 %) stated that lessees did fulfil their
obligation on the contract in front of them while 8 % of respondents
responded
that lessees fulfilled their obligation on the lease of land shares.
A
significant
number of respondents (44 %) reported that they were not satisfied with
the
lease terms and another half of respondents stated that they were only
partly satisfied
with the lease term. Only 4 % of respondents expressed satisfaction
with the lease
terms. Mainly, it was the pensioners and elder respondents who
expressed part
satisfaction with the lease terms.
Respondents
were asked about their reasons for concluding lease contract with
agricultural
entities. The following responses were obtained: no alternative options
for
renting out the land shares (38 %), it was the sole beneficial proposal
for the
lease of the land shares (8%) and it was possibility to get benefits
from the lease
of the land shares (46 %). On the basis
of this result it is evident that not so many farming entities work in
the rural
area and that the market for leasing land shares is not competitive. A
few
farms are interested in renting land shares and they offer similar
terms of
land share lease in their proposal. It is proved by prevailing
responses on
absence of alternative options.
As one
positive sign for agriculture could be the considerable number of
operating
peasant farms and therefore the respondents were asked whether they
would
establish a peasant farm. This question is very important, because this
would
give some ideas about the future situation in the agricultural sector
in Kazakhstan.
First of
all, land share owners were asked about their future use of land if
they would receive
land tenure into private ownership or by use right. The majority of
land share
owners (74 %) intended to rent out their land plot and out of this
group a considerable
part (58 %) intended to rent out to those who would pay more. Thus the
owners
of land shares prefer to get lease payments rather than be involved in
farming.
It is explicable by the fact that many respondents are elderly or
pensioners
and they are not able to conduct private farming. Only a small numbers
of
respondents (22 %) expressed the desire to be engaged in crop growing
and only
4 % of respondents intended to use the land plot for cattle breeding.
Thus, it
is not surprising to get such a result on the desire of land share
owners to
establish peasant farm. The majority of
land share owners (67 %) responded negatively concerning the
establishment of a
peasant farm and the remaining respondents answered that they did not
know
whether they would establish peasant farm.
The
responses of land share owners showed that the main obstacle to
establishing
peasant farms is the financially burdened procedure (72 % of
respondents) and the
other main obstacle is the bureaucracy of local state bodies concerning
the registration
of peasant farm (10 %). A small group (10 %) had difficulties in
answering
while the remaining respondents gave other reasons, such as lack of
interest,
inability to work with land and elder age.
The
owners of land share owners were asked to indicate the obstacles in the
operation
of peasant farm. Respondent could indicate more than one condition and
the responses
were:
-
absence of financing from banks and
financial establishments (28 %);
-
absence of agricultural machinery and rent
of machinery (46%);
-
high prices for services for grain storage
and cleaning (30%);
-
absence of possibility to sell the grain
without intermediaries on appropriate
price (44 %); and
-
ignorance
of modern technologies on cultivation of crop production.
Finally,
the owner of land share were asked about whether the peasant farm might
unite
to form cooperatives and unions for joint activity in the purchase of
agricultural inputs such as seed, fuel, fertilizes, rent of
agricultural
machinery and sales of agricultural commodities. A majority (78 %)
answered
positively while only 2 % of respondents answered negatively. But 16 %
of
respondents stated that they did not know about the possibility of
uniting
peasant farms into cooperatives and union and 4 % of respondents had
difficulties in answering.
Those
who
responded positively were asked to indicate the number of persons they
would unit
with for joint work. Among these respondents approximately 51%
respondents stated
that they would unit with, at least with five farmers, 23 % and 18 % of
respondents said three persons and ten persons, respectively. The
remaining respondents
had difficulties in determining the number of participants. Thus, the
land
share owners expressed that they would be able to cooperate with other
farmers
and the most frequently mentioned ideal number of participants was five.
4.6. Conclusion on conducted survey.
The
survey showed that the distribution of land shares to rural residents
did provide
them with a meaningful benefit. Despite land share owners reporting
that they
receive an insignificant benefit from rental payment compared with
total family
income these rental payments did provide rural residents with feed and
forage
for their household’s cattle and animals. In case of the termination of
these
rental payments the rural family members, who already have low cash
incomes,
would have to buy winter feed and forage for cattle at market price or
to hire
some machinery for cutting grass and preparation of forage. These are
considerably
higher compared with lessee prices. Thus the rental payment is crucial
for
rural residents.
The
majority
of land lessees are large private enterprises and they have more
possibility to
provide the owners of land share with forage and other agricultural
commodities.
In this sense they can afford to sell the forage and hay at prices,
which are considerably
lower compared with market prices.
Due to
fact that a substantial number of survey respondents (42%) are rural
resident
of eldest ages (50 years and more) it is understandable why there were
not so
many positive responses to the questions concerning the establishment
of peasant
farms. All those people are unable to farm for various reasons such as
age,
lack of relevant knowledge and experience, absence of financial
resources and
others. But the main problem is the inability for proper work in
farming, because
many respondents worked as an ordinary worker, mainly in cattle
breeding. Thus
the lease of their land shares has been an important source of income
for a considerable
number of rural residents. The payments in kind provide them with a
meaningful
benefit that helps maintain raising livestock for own consumption and
sales as
well.
Literature
1. Abdraimov B. Zh. Land Process in Republic of Kazakhstan, Almaty, 2001.
2. Agency
of the Republic of Kazakhstan, Statistical Yearbook of Kazakhstan, 2002.
3. Agency
of the Republic of Kazakhstan, Regions of Kazakhstan, 2002.
4. Asian
Development Bank, TA No 2356 “Strengthening the Implementation of Agriculture
Sector Reforms”, Danagro Advisor a/s,
September 1996.
5. Asian
Development Bank, TA No 3898-KAZ “Participatory Rural Sector Planning and Development“, Scanagri, February
2003.
6. Asian
Development Bank TA No 6078- REG “Rural Finance in Central Asia”, 2004.
7. Centre
of System Research of Administration of the President of Republic
of Kazakhstan, Land Code (informative support to
rural
area), Astana, 2004.
8. Espolov
T. E., Grigoruk V.V. Formation of Market System of Land Relations in Kazakhstan.
9. Hadzhiev A.H., Land Legislation of the Republic of Kazakshtan, 2002.
10. Rural
Population of Kyzylorda oblast: a Portrait in Numbers 2002.
11. UNDP,
Human Development Report, Kazakhstan 2002.
12. UNDP,
Poverty in Kazakhstan: Causes and Cures, Kazakhstan, 2004.
13. RDI
Report on Foreign Aid and Development # 119, The Impact of Land Titling
in Ukraine: An examination of the Results from
800 Person-Sample Survey, 2003.
14. World Bank, Land Reform in Ukraine, Washington, D.C.,1997.
|