Sorin Ioniţă |
|||||||||
|
Corruption
as a symptom of opacity and poor policy making Research project funded
by the IPF
program of OSI, The
more corrupt the state, the more numerous the laws
Timetable- Publius Cornelius Tacitus - Issues and advocacy plan A. Problem
definition The basic
idea of this project is that
corruption and the mishandling of public funds in transition countries
are to a
large extent just symptoms of two deeper institutional shortcomings: ·
The
opacity of the public institutions,
of policies and their effects. Most of the time the
main problem is not
that relevant pieces of information are not disclosed to the public,
but that
they are not produced within the public agencies in the first place,
although
they should be among the most important management instruments to
improve performance
in the state sector. ·
The flawed
policy process, probably the
most crucial (and ignored) source of poor governance, is characterized
by
little public consultations, hasty decisions and poor implementation
capacity.
If at all, the public debates and identification of crucial trade-offs
occur after policies are (or are supposed to
be) implemented, not before, which creates uncertainty, confusion and
ultimately mistrust in public institutions. The immediate symptom of
this model
of governing by default is the large gap between written plans and
strategies,
on the one hand, and social realities on the other. This flawed
decision-making
pattern verifies the worst expectations of citizens, as it is very
permeable to
rent-seeking and typically leads to selective enforcement of rules. Briefly
put,
corruption – broadly defined so as to include rent-seeking, state
capture,
deliberate misallocation of public funds and the exchange of favors
that can
take even non-monetary forms – is only a by-product of a flawed policy
making
process. This being so, there is currently little incentive for
citizens
to participate in making decisions, as long as policies are muddled,
inconsistent and ultimately non-binding. Important public actions in
society
occur mostly by default, by formal laws and regulations being enforced
selectively, after different groups struggle for the best possible
arrangement
(the best menu of rules applicable in their case). The policy-by-default model
of governing is damaging for the society in general because: it is
unpredictable; it is opaque, making hard to evaluate costs and
benefits; it
discourages broad involvement, and so forgoes fresh private resources
and
ideas; it is ultimately ineffective, creating huge deadweight costs.
Due to
this ah-hoc nature of governance, crucial public choices either pass
unnoticed
or are obscured on purpose (to avoid divisions, public criticism, etc).
When
this happens, the hard decisions are postponed, and therefore taken
implicitly
by the bureaucracy in the process of implementation. This is why many
times the
secondary acts (administrative norms) that follow a law are more
important than
the law itself – actually, they make law. There is nothing new or
peculiar to transition countries in having erratic and opaque policies,
an
unclear agenda at the top, little public consultation, poor
coordination, and a
weak civil service overstepping its mandate when making crucial
decisions by
default in the implementation process. In a book on policies in
developing
countries, Marilee Grindle argues that one of their obvious
characteristics is
that the focus of participation and conflict occurs primarily at the
implementation or the output stage[1].
This contrasts with the experience of the Mutatis mutandis, the
analysis
is instructive when translated into the post-communist space. Communism
has
left behind a tradition of policy making which does not encourage broad
and open
consultations, considering and costing-out alternative courses of
action, or
balancing trade-offs. Instead, the agenda is set in a close circle of
technocrats and approved by the key political players (who may or may
not
coincide with the official political hierarchy). However, the formal
policy set
from the top is merely a basis for perpetual negotiations – vertical
and
horizontal[3]
– in the public administration and the political system occurring
during the
implementation stage. Substantial deviations from the original goals
are
tolerated depending on the informal power of each actor involved.
Formal
policies do exist, as well as other official norms and regulations, but
they
tend to be more or less fictional, many times the public institutions
being the
first to ignore them. When this system becomes
well-entrenched policies are (i) numerous and volatile (ii) and
designed
without regard to the feasibility of implementation, since they are not
meant
to be consistently implemented anyway, but to be used instrumentally as
weapons
in power struggles among groups. Interests are balanced not during the
process
of reaching a decision, but in the implementation process, and the most
valuable asset in this process is control over the enforcement
mechanisms.
Horizontal accountability bodies – nominally independent institutions
such as
the administrative judicial system, public auditors – are therefore
weak and
politicized. This situation comes close to what has been described in
the
development literature as weak governance,
and it is arguably an entrenched reality in many transition countries,
particularly in South-Eastern Europe. B. Project objectives While this brief
description
points at the vastity and profoundness of the problem, step by step
remedies
are possible, however. First we need to document and measure it more
precisely,
beyond the sweeping description sketched here. Convincing descriptions
and
illustrations, if properly done, can help by increasing the visibility
of some
parts of the broader policy-making process which are otherwise
considered too
technical and intricate by most citizens and opinion leaders (such as
budgetary
allocations). Second, precise and realistic institutional remedies must
de
devised aimed at fixing some of the flaws identified. As a policy area broadly
defined, this project will focus on the intergovernmental
financial transfers (money
circulating between the national and various tiers of local governments
in a
country) and other special funds and allocations performed by central
agencies
which presuppose substantial spending and/or investment affecting local
communities. Since all transition countries are aggressively
decentralizing
government functions and resources, the share of these funds in the
total
budget is rapidly increasing – for example in In this project we will
carry
out activities on three dimensions: 1.
Devise a system of quantitative indicators to measure the extent to which
the policy-by-default model corresponds to
reality in the area discussed above, and what are its effects. Since
the budget
is the typical embodiment of the main policy choices, whether implicit
or
explicit, the set of indicators will be built mostly based on it. ·
Budget volatility, i.e.
the tolerance to deviations
in execution on the main chapters ·
In cases where policies
imply territorial
allocations, the fraction of appropriations and spending done without
explicit
criteria ·
When
criteria of allocation and spending do exist, a measure of
deviation
from them will be built in order to evaluate the accuracy of enforcing 2.
A number of three or
four case studies will be developed on
important sections of the policy area defined above, where policies-by-default
seems to be the best explanatory model.
Particular attention will be devoted to the role played by
institutional
design, incentives of stakeholders and the resulting political choices
which
may explain the patterns described at point 1 above. The aim here is to
develop
good governance lessons from this analysis and summarize them in the
form of an agenda for change in the sectors
studies through the cases. The vision underpinning this analysis is
that of
improving governance through better measurement and transparentization.
In this
sense transparency is not only something that happens (or not) at the
interface
with the citizen, but indeed a principle built into the own internal
procedures
of the public sector. 3.
In the most pro-active
part of the project,
a brief Citizens' Budget Guide will
be edited and disseminated, with a focus on the most "sensitive"
areas of the budget described above. The target group of this Guide,
edited for
the first time in C. Deliverables and dissemination ·
Policy paper including
the evaluation, case studies
and policy recommendations produced (points 1 and 2). It will be edited
in both
electronic form and hardcopy, in both Romanian and English, and
disseminated to
the Romanian media and broader public, and discussed in two public
workshops. · Two public workshops organized by the Romanian Academic Society (SAR, Bucharest-based think tank) with people from the relevant central and local public institutions, to debate the findings and recommendations included in the policy paper. ·
The Citizens' Budget
Guide, in Romanian, in both
electronic form and hardcopy. This will also be disseminated through
opinion
leaders and the media, be made available freely on SAR's webpage, and
pushed
into the public attention by a series of presentations and press
conferences.
If successful, the possibility will be explored to contract a printed
edition
with one of the Romanian academic publishing houses. D. Regional relevance ·
The work on the
indicators defined at point 1 may
have piloting value: the set of indicators can form the basis for a
subsequent
cross-country benchmarking study in the region – a quantitative
approach to the
comparative assessment of the quality of governance which goes beyond
the
typical opinion survey indicators. Objective measurements of weak
governance
are both a good diagnostic tool and a trigger for public action in the
fight
against misgovernance and corruption. ·
The analysis and reform
proposals at point 2 may
also have a regional dimension, as the problems identified and lessons
learned,
though developed on the example of ·
A Regional Citizens'
Budget Guide, following up on
the few such existing initiatives and incorporating the most relevant
country-specific conclusions and trends, may also be an idea worth
exploring. E. Connections with
other OSI / CEU
programs ·
Discuss with the
organizers to include a
presentation / module / section in the 2006 course Strategic
Corruption Control and Organizational Integrity (also
held in 2005), organized by SUN. Preliminary discussions as our IPF
projects
advances will be held with the CPS / Public Integrity Education Network
staff
who are also involved in organizing the SUN course. ·
A workshop may be held
by our IPF group on Corruption and Policymaking in
Transition together with the students and staff
of the
Public Policy MA program at CEU who have similar interests, under the
umbrella
of the department. If announced well in advance and held in early
December / or
late January, the workshop may be an opportunity for the CEU MA
students to
present their term papers that may fit this topic. ·
To the extent that it
addresses practical issues of
public administration reform or public budgeting, the activity of this
workgroup may be of interests for the Local
Government and Public Service Initiative program of OSI as well.
[1] Grindle, M., 1980.
"Introduction", in M. Grindle (ed) Politics and Policy
Implementation in the [2] Op. cit.,
p. 18. [3] We use here the
terminology
employed by Janos Kornai in his description of the Communist regime as
perfectly unpredictable, where the official plan was in fact only a
loose
guideline and what happened in practice was the result of power games
and
negotiations – Kornai J, 1992. The
Socialist System. The Political Economy of Communism.
|