Issue Paper


Overcoming ‘State Capture’ as a Key Cause of Misgovernance and Corruption: The Case of Serbia

 
Issue Paper

(1) Large-scale and systemic (political) corruption has acquired such proportions in Serbia that it may undermine the success of its transition. I have identified the phenomenon of state capture as the key cause which may result in the failure of Serbia’s transition. Literature defines state capture as ‘seizure’ of laws to the advantage of corporative business via influential political links in the parliament and government. I have defined it more broadly because of the Serbian tradition in which political (party) elites is the main agents appropriating the state and public assets. Their actions are geared at staying in power[1], at using their offices to consolidate the financial power and influence of their parties, at employing their relatives and party cronies, but also at achieving their personal and corporative interests. In this context, state capture entails a set of mechanisms by which political elites appropriate state institutions and functions, using them as their own and in their own interest.

 

(2) My initial hypothesis is that party leaderships are the chief mediators in the exchange of services between the state and the political parties. [2] I will first review the theoretical and historical causes of state capture and then focus on the recent ones. From the viewpoint of systems theory, the high convertibility of political offices and their domination over other social sub-systems indicates an integrative deficit, compensated by obligatory ideology.  Serbia lived for half a century in such a system – the one of ‘real socialism’. Amidst the global collapse of real socialism, Serbia revitalized the old system by adapting it to extremist nationalism and preparing for the wars of the nineties. The ensuing centralization stripped local governments of much of their jurisdiction and took over their property (as yet not restored). Under global pressure, a multi-party system was introduced in authoritarian circumstances. The war economy and international blockade encouraged large-scale smuggling of cigarettes, oil, weapons and drugs, organized by the state and entrusted to its cronies. The plants and businesses that still operated successfully were also entrusted to reliable people,[3] who appropriated the socialist companies they managed, acquired riches in exchange for regularly paying state racket. As the nouveaux riches were the first to realize that the regime was to be ousted, they secretly funded opposition parties to preserve their property. The oligarchic structure was practically formed during the old regime.  When the new authorities took over (October 2000), they launched transition reforms but went on using the inherited infrastructure of power in internal clashes and 'positioning' of their parties.

 

(3) The following issues bring us to the present. How were the state capture mechanisms incorporated in the multi-party system and how was the party-state amalgam achieved?

 

(a) The chief mechanism lies in the division of powers, based on a secret coalition agreement. The agreement sets out the percentages of power each ruling party gets in accordance with the number of seats won in the Parliament.[4] The second part of the agreement focuses on content and classifies all offices by portfolios (horizontally and vertically). State capture and monopolies constitute part of the division – each coalition party has received a number of related portfolios to manage and staff by itself. Power has been feudalized – each ruling party is the absolute ruler of its own fief and the government has operated as a confederation of 'power fiefs'. For instance, one party has been allocated all portfolios regarding finance; its leader is the Finance Minister[5] and he has appointed reliable associates and party cronies to the posts below him; the same party has been given rule over other central institutions and services having to do with finance, such as the National Bank, Tax Administration, Customs Administration, Lottery, Securities Commission, et al. Apart from the horizontal rule, this party also rules vertically and its local boards recruit heads of the local tax administration offices, customs bureaus, lotteries, etc. in all municipalities and cities of Serbia. Another party, the strongest in the coalition, sovereignly rules over the police and intelligence agency through its officials. The Police Minister has replaced 700 senior police officials since he took over. And so on, from party to party. Moreover, there is no audit or supervision of budget spending, nor any civilian control of the police. 

 

(b) Another important dimension of state capture, when connected with the first one, entails appointing leading party officials (presidents, their deputies, etc) to manage the 'fiefs' although they simultaneously actively discharge their party offices. As a party leader – feudalist has MPs in the Parliament providing majority support to the Government, corruption is practically incorporated in the manner in which the government operates.[6] Ministerial abuses literally go unpunished. If a minister were dismissed, he would withdraw his MPs and the Government would lose the parliamentary majority and fall.

 

(c) Party chiefs' control over seats in the Parliament is another relevant corruptive mechanism of state capture.[7] The party chiefs compose the candidates’ lists and decide which candidates will enter Parliament after the elections, irrespectively of their order on the list. If an MP is disloyal or does not vote as instructed, s/he is stripped of his or her mandate and thrown out of the Parliament.[8] To cement their obedience, MPs are corrupted by being given money for trips they never made and parliament committee sessions they never attended. But their main advantages lie in immunity from the Law on Conflict of Interests and opportunity to earn additional income as directors, management board chairpersons or members of public companies and companies partly or wholly owned by the state, seats allocated to them by their parties. They are allowed to accumulate offices: MPs can simultaneously be mayors, members of local governments and parliaments, business advisers, city land bureau directors or engage in private business.  

 

(d) The amount of power in the hands of the parties becomes even more evident if one is aware of the fact that some 40,000 offices in Serbia are divided in the above manner. This both undermines public interests and constitutes widespread discrimination of citizens on grounds of party affiliation. Senior management positions are not advertised.[9] Additionally, parties manage public companies owned by the state i.e. the parties.[10]

 

(e) Finally, the relationship between the parties (government) and the business constitutes the key aspect of state capture. The Law on Funding of Political Parties was passed in 2003 but its implementation did not diminish corruption in this area. The Law does not provide for the establishment of a separate institution to monitor the funding of parties and the body charged with supervision (Parliament Finance Committee) has practically rendered the law inapplicable. The law suffers from numerous other deficiencies.[11]  Not only did the Law fail to make the operations of the parties transparent (it may have rendered them even less transparent); it also enabled parties to draw between 5 and 7 million Euros a year from the state budget. There are many indications that politicians have systematically been creating loops of companies through which they have acquired a lot of money. [12]

 

From the policy point of view, eliminating of the corruptive mechanisms of state capture simultaneously constitutes measures for curbing excessive political power, such as the strengthening of individual responsibility of the MP’s[13], the de-politicization of public functions via competition, preventing ‘feudal’ government coalitions, the exclusion of function-accumulation, the adopting of new laws on conflict of interest and party financing, the strengthening of monitoring and regulatory institutions in these areas, and the support of faster privatization of public enterprises.

 



[1]Ministers are not even concealing from the public that they are spending money from the budget on buying votes. The Capital Investments Minister, for instance, has offered citizens to pave their local roads if they joined his party, setting the price at "fifty votes per one kilometer of the road", Weekly Vreme, 18 May 2006.

[2] It may also be presumed that the visible consolidation of power of the parties, including the promotion of their internal party oligarchic structures, is meant to uphold their image as reliable guarantors of business elite interests. The trend is that the few people closest to the party president accumulate a large number of public offices because control is easier than if the offices were dispersed amongst a greater number of people. See: Vesna Pešic, “Unblocking Transitional Changes and Intra-Party Democracy”, in Zoran Lutovac (ed.)  Democracy in Political Parties,  Belgrade, 2006  

 

[3] Research into the origin of the present-day economic elite indicates it was recruited from socialist companies; their former directors, experts and managers, once part of the nomenclature, are the 'tycoons' of today. Mladen Lazić, “Recruitment of the New Economic and Political Elites”, Republika, June 2006. 

[4]Given the current constellation of political forces and the proportional election system, no party can win a majority, wherefore coalitions are formed at all levels of authority. The first post-Milošević government was formed by 18 parties, but had avoided the 'feudal' division of portfolios. The current government is formed by four parties; at the local government level, coalitions are broader and their clashes over division of power are the cause of constant decompositions and recompositions of local governments.

[5] The current Finance Minister was the Governor of the National Bank of Serbia in the previous government and had over the course of several years appointed all bank directors and managers.

[6] For instance, the Capital Investments Minister publicly admitted he had not respected the procurement procedure when he was buying Swedish train wagons; he has, however, suffered no consequences because his dismissal would have prompted the withdrawal of his MPs' support to the Government and the Government would have fallen. The Finance Minister found himself in the same situation, but the same mechanism of total irresponsibility was applied, justified by the need to 'preserve the majority'. 

[7] All parties have obliged their MPs to sign blank resignations prior to entering Parliament. These resignations are kept by the party leaders, who activate them as needed.

[8] Two MPs of the 'financial party' (that of the Finance Minister) said they would not vote for the 2006 state budget just before the vote in November 2005. They were excluded from the Parliament the very next day.

[9] Under the State Administration Law passed last year, senior administrative positions will also be publicly advertised. The Law has not come into effect yet and many have serious doubts about how it will be implemented and whether it will be monitored.

[10]  Privatization has not been completed in Serbia and 50% of companies are still state (and socially) owned. According to NBS 2004 data (data for 2005 have not been released yet), financial reports were submitted by 521 public companies employing 190,000 workers (i.e. 16% of Serbia's blue-collar workforce). The value of their capital stood at 932 billion dinars and their collective losses at 21 billion dinars. Source: Conference on Public Companies, Center for Liberal-Democratic Studies, transcript, www.B92.net, 10 June, 2006. 

[11] Zoran Stoiljkovic, Miodrag Milosavljevic, Mirjana Simic, Djordje Vukovic, Monitoring finansiranja izbornih kampanja, CeSID, Beograd, 2005

[12] The detailed reports about such cases were submitted to the Government by the Anti-Corruption Council but they have never been reviewed.

[13] The electoral legislation in Serbia has to be changed to make clear that mandates belong to the individual MPs and not to the parties; the parties and coalitions must announce in advance the numerical order of the candidates who will enter the parliament from the lists, and not be allowed to choose, after the elections, which candidate will get the mandate. In such a practice, citizens never know who they are voting for. See recommendations of the Venetian Commission on Serbian Electoral Legislation, Danas, June 22, 2006.