LINKING GENDER AND GOVERNANCE

 

Introduction

 

Governance is one of the key concepts in current development debate. The concept of governance which includes accountability, participation, transparency and human rights as its basic components is considered as crucial requirement for the success of development especially in developing countries. International development agencies with diverse interpretation, yet similar emphasis on governance substantiate these components of governance in term of good governance. Since the 1990s good governance become an issue of conditionality in promoting accountable and effective governance in aid recipient countries. However, concerns on the imposition of Western concept of governance and good governance by international development agencies on developing countries and the inconsistencies in the achievement of the application of ‘good governance’ among developing countries bring concept of governance and good governance into the centre of development debate.

 

This chapter will review the principles of good governance and tensions it creates when implemented in a way that neglect the diversity of cultural, political and historical contexts among countries. It will first elaborate on debates on the definition and usage of governance. However, this chapter does not intend to built fix definition of governance rather it will elaborate on discussion on diverse concepts of governance in gaining insight to the complexities of governance in its implementation. I will argue that since governance is an interactive process of governing, governance approach rather than government approach provides a framework in examining processes of governing. This approach also provides a space for women as one of the stakeholders. By focusing on the interaction and interdependencies among diverse stakeholders at different level, concept of governance provides a space for the emergent of women as one of the various stakeholders in development. Thus, I will use governance concept primarily as a descriptive and analytical tool through which several questions crucial in understanding governance can be posed: What are the notions of governance? What kind of interaction will best served the inclusion of the variety of stakeholders in influencing development policies? If governance means the plurality in interaction, what about the accessibility of women? In what ways do concept of government and governance differ in explaining the empowerment of women in local development? What about women perception of what constitutes as a good governance? Do criteria of good governance mention any minimal standard of women involvement in decision making? Do the diverse definitions of good governance have incorporated a gendered understanding of policy and implementation?

 

 

GOVERNANCE

 

Governance has long been equated with ‘governing ‘the process aspect of government (Mayntz 1998). The first paradigm of a theory of political governance perceives governing as steering, a top down approach in policy making and policy implementation (Mayntz 1998). In steering, governing becomes a linear model in which power is used to secure the implementation of policies that have been determined by the rulers. The strict division between the ruler and the ruled create the zero-sum game of power. Deviations of the ruled reactions towards the determined policies, norms and rules are considered as threats towards the power of the ruler. Thus, it creates suspicion towards each other.  This mode of governing make the implementation and enforcement of policies and programmes become more intensive and expensive (Dunsire 1993:24) since the state has all the responsibility and act as a single agent in policy making and implementation. The huge burden on the state, the rigidity and clumsiness of its bureaucratic structure reduces the capability of the state to establish close relation with the society which then contributes to its lost of  legitimacy (Peters & Pierre 1998).   ‘Men should be governed in such a way that they do not regard themselves as being governed, but as following their own bent and their own free choice in their manner of life; in such a way, then, that they are restrained only by love of freedom, desire to increase their possessions, and the hope of obtaining offices of the state’ (Spinoza 1677 cited in Dunsire 1993:30).

 

Dissatisfaction to state’s performance as the centre of political control in dealing with pluralist demand from public gave rise to governance. Discussion on governing diverts its attention to alternative forms of societal governance which put more value on the potentials and capabilities of the society in governing. The search towards alternative forms of societal governance develops into two separate line of discussion the market principles and horizontal self-organisation (Mayntz 1998). Based on the political ideology of neo-liberalism and Thatcherism, the market principles emphasise on deregulation and privatisation as main instruments in achieving both economic growth and economic efficiency. The private sector rather than the state is considered as being more effective as agents of development (Mayntz 1998; Peters& Pierre 1998).  In horizontal self-organisation the state actors still occupies a special position as participants in policy networks in which they still maintain crucial means of intervention even where there is devolution of decision making to institutions of societal government (Mayntz 1998). Commitment to have continuous dialogues between the state and private sector becomes the basis for the working of self-organisation governance. Continuous dialogue and exchanges of information reduce the problem of bounded rationality while at the same time reduce opportunism through locking governance partners into a range of interdependent decisions over a mixture of short-, medium- and long-term horizons; and building on the interdependencies and risks associated with ‘asset specificity’ by encouraging solidarity among those involved. The network between the state and private sector which is characterised by interdependency between actors function as mechanism for negotiations in mobilising consensus and building mutual understanding. The dialogic rationality of governance is ensured through the nature of reciprocity between actors in which in order to gain some political influence and benefit from a better overall function of the system individual economic partners give some of their autonomy to the state. On the other hand the state gives some of its authority in decision making to have influence over economic activities (Jessop 1998).

 

Diverse definitions of governance emerge in this new paradigm of governance. The UNDP (2000) defines governance as the exercise of political, economic and administrative authority in the management of a country’s affairs at all levels UNDP. This definition equates governance with the management of society.

 

However, the complexity of the interdependency between the state, community and private sector in fulfilling the diverse public demands and interests implies that governance cannot be limited to managing the society efficiently. The World Conference on Metropolitan Governance in its meeting in Tokyo 1993 reject the reduction of governance to management and the division of governance into merely the political and technical dimensions. Governance is perceived as including the visions and strategic decisions of a country. Governance has five fundamental dimensions: political, contextual, constitutional, legal and administrative/managerial. It implies bottom-up decision making; having all concerned people at every level of government and non-government organisations (Beal 1996:4).  Hence, the meaning of governance embraces not only efficient management but also the quality of civic engagement in the processes and structures of governance.

 

Pattern of interaction and network in governing, then, become the dominant feature of governance in this new paradigm. Using the ‘duality structure approach’ Kooiman (1993:258) explains governance as the ‘emerging pattern (or order) of a system that is both the outcome of social processes (interactions) as well as the medium through which actors can act and interpret this pattern’. Concurs with this definition, Jessop (1998:30) refers to governance as the models and manner of governing, government to the institutions and agents charged with governing, and governing to the act of governing itself’. These interpretations of governance concept provide insights in defining the relationship between governing and governance.

 

Thus, as Mayntz (1998:1-2)) notes that recently there is a shift in the development of governance paradigm from political guidance or steering (the first paradigm) to:

1. Governance as a new mode of governing that is distinct from the hierarchical control mode, a more cooperative mode where state and non-state actors participate in mixed public/private networks.

2. Governance as different modes of coordinating individual actions, or basic forms of social order.

This new paradigm of governance reveals a shift from a more traditional patterns of governing as ‘one way traffic’/unilateral focus (from those governing to the governed) to a ‘2 way traffic’/interactionist focus in which ‘(dis) qualities of social-political systems and their governance are viewed from the perspective of the recognition of mutual needs and capacities’ (Kooiman 1993:35-36).

 

The notions of governance brought about by the new paradigm provide a dynamic approach in understanding governance in the ways:  

1.      the notion of governance requires us to focus on active processes rather than passive, static accounts of institutions. While an understanding of the structure of political institutions is indispensable, it allows for the exploration towards the ways in which the key actors have used those structures and institutions; what resources, options and strategies make available to those actors?

2.      the notion of governance suggests a process of rule making in which government and political elites are locked into economic and social networks – these may be formal or informal, vertical hierarchies or more horizontal egalitarian relationships, cooperative or  conflictual (Goldblatt 1998:1-2).

 

These notions of governance rest on 3 theoretical principles or premises: 

-the existence of a crisis of governability

-that this crisis reflects the exhaustion of the traditional form of state intervention

-the emergence of a tendency or of a convergent political trend in all the developed countries that is giving rise to a new form of governance better adapted to the context ([Merrien 1998:57).

 

Despite diverse definition and interpretation on governance, debates on governance seem to agree that governance refer to styles in governing in which stakeholders create dependent network. In these governing styles the boundaries between and within public and private sectors have become blurred.

 

Whilst identifies six separate uses of governance: as the minimal state, as corporate governance, as the new public management, as ‘good governance’, as socio-cybernetic system, and as self-organizing networks, Rhodes (1997) also identifies the shared characteristics of governance:

1. Interdependence between organisations. Governance is broader than government, covering non-state actors. Changing the boundaries of the state meant the boundaries between public, private and voluntary sectors became shifting and opaque.

2. Continuing interactions between network members, caused by the need to exchange resources and negotiate shared purposes.

3. Game-like interactions, rooted in trust and regulated by rules of the game negotiated and agreed by network participants.

4. A significant degree of autonomy from the state. Networks are not accountable to the state; they are self-organizing. Although the state does not occupy a sovereign position, it can indirectly steer networks’ (Rhodes 1997:57)

 

From the foregoing discussion it is obvious that interaction and network among mutually dependent power become basic interrelated concepts in governance. Differ from the concept of government which concerns mainly with institutional aspects of policy making and  policy implementation, and  adopted a top-down perspective, concept of governance focuses on processes of governing and interactions among diverse actors as mutually dependent power. Governance is about managing networks, not only by government but also by the interaction between government and society; private and public institutions (Rhodes 1997:52). The essence of governance is its focus on governing mechanisms which do not rest on recourse to the authority and sanctions of government (Stoker 1998). It is a dynamic process and produces by the interaction of public and private (Kooiman 1993:2). The concept of governance which emphasises on processes of governing rather than on institutional aspects allows for greater attention to link various actors and use their potential to deal with development problems which would otherwise be neglected if we only discuss about government.

 

To some, the dispersion of political control and policy making to collections of non-state actors in the new paradigm of governance may be perceived as the loss of the state power and control (Merrien 1998; Peters&Pierre 1998). However, this shift from government to governance in which there is power transfer from the state to the society cannot be considered as the diminishing power of the state. The concept of governance does not mean the state loose its power or withdraw from the activities in governing or separate from the society, rather it is a changing form of state’s control (Bhatta 1998) and a shift in the way of governing in which state role play its role as a balancer of social forces and social interests and enabler to social actors and systems in order that these actors may organize themselves (Kooiman 1993). For example, in the collibrition mode of governance, the state as a balancer influences and directs relations between social actors into a more desirable balance (Dunsire 1993).

 

In arguing that governance implies for changes in ways of governing rather than the lost of state control, Kooiman (1993:2) points out that in the ‘co’ forms of governance such as: co-steering, co-managing, co-producing and co-allocating (social-political way of governing), public or private actors do not act separately but in conjunction, together, in combination’ that is to say in ‘co’ arrangement’. He further on argues that ‘Instead of relying on the state or the market, social-political governance is directed at the creation of patterns of interaction in which political and traditional hierarchical governing and social self-organisation are complementary, in which responsibility and accountability for interventions is spread over public and actors, but leaves enough autonomy on the micro level’ (Kooiman 1993:252).

 

Hence, in governance the responsibility between public and private become more diffused. Interaction based on the recognition of interdependencies since the strength and weaknesses among stakeholders differ. To succeed, governing needs to cooperate and integrate stakeholders’ contributions to strengthen each other.

 

In governance, the quality of civic engagement is of equal importance as with the governing capacity of government.  At this point, the synergistic relationship between government and the governed is crucial. Evans (1996) provides a useful definition of synergy as mutually reinforcing relations between governments and groups of engaged citizens which rests on relational basis: ‘An intimate interconnection and intermingling among public and private actors is combined with a well-defined complementary division of labor between the bureaucracy and local citizens, mutually recognized and accepted by both sides’. As enabler , government is expected to ‘enable not only highly organized and strong actors but also individual citizens and social movements to infiltrate within the administration and to be represented within the policy making process ‘(Kooiman 1993:257). Thus, synergy goes beyond the question of how to make the strength and weakness of diverse stakeholders becomes complementary to the embeddedness between society and government.

 

Order, rule and collective action are the expected outcome of both government and governance. ‘Governance is ultimately concerned with creating the conditions for ordered rule and collective action. The outputs of governance are not therefore different from those of government. It is rather a matter of a difference in processes ‘(Stoker 1998:17). Whereas government (as the first paradigm of governance) reveals the hierarchic mode of governing in which government officials and institutions guide or steer policy development and implementation, in governance these policies and implementation are determined through interaction of various stakeholders.

 

Although in general, there seem to be the similarity of the outcomes between government and governance, that is order, yet the concept of governance requires greater degree of  diverse stakeholders’ participation in achieving the objective. The concept of governance also implies the existence of network in which diverse stakeholders depend on each other. In this new paradigm of governance, government is only one part of the components in the network of governing which has to interact independently with other components. Interdependencies between stakeholders imply that none of them has absolute control over the processes of governing which will enlarge the maneouvering space for diverse stakeholders in influencing the processess  (Peters& Pierre 1998).

 

 

Good  Governance

 

Governance is a buzzword among donors’ development agencies and it gains interest in the 1990s in relation with World Bank’s findings of the significance of a country’s capacity as a component in achieving a success and sustainable development  (Bhatta 1998:4). The Western notion of governance is developed by international donor in incorporating good governance as a condition in giving aid to developing countries.

 

International aid donors although similarly emphasis on the significance of governance, have broad interpretation in defining governance ranging from neutral label of governance into a more political definition of good governance. Under the label of ‘good government’ the Department for International Development Administration (formerly UK Overseas Development Administration) provides an example for an “overtly political” definition of governance (Minogue, Polidano &Hulme 1998:5-6) as it contains of four main components:

1. Legitimacy implies that a system of government must operate with the consent of those who governed, who must therefore have the means to give or withhold that assent; such legitimacy is seen in the British policy document as most likely to be guaranteed by pluralist, multi-party democracy.

2. Accountability involves the existence of mechanisms which ensure that public officials and political leaders are answerable for their actions and use of public resources, and will require transparent government and a free media.

3. Competence in making and executing appropriate public policies and delivering efficient public services is essential

4. Respect for law and protection of human rights should buttress the entire system of good government. 

 

On the other hand the UNDP uses a more neutral label of sound governance which good governance is defined as addressing the allocation and management of resources to respond to collective problems and that it is characterised by participation, transparency, accountability, rule of law, effectiveness and equity (UNDP2000). This definition is more sensitive to cultural and political differences among countries since it recognises the differences in governments’ response towards the ideas of participation, individuality, order and authority and also the possibility of differences in combining efficiency and accountability across diverse forms of political authority (Minogue et al 1995).  

 

The World Bank has an in-between interpretation of governance which leads to a seemingly contradictory strategy. Whilst its documents emphasis on professional policy making and management in using resources effectively, thus, policy making of political interventions should be avoided, yet, by also emphasising on the significance of strengthening the civil society, World Bank has frequently passed the border of its neutrality which was reflected in its inability to avoid political connotations of nearly half its governance lending projects in 1991-1993 (Minogue et al 1995).

 

 Linking good governance to development Larmour (2000) provides another useful classification of the definition of governance as:

1. Democratic governance which concerns with legitimacy, accountability, and human rights. It addresses traditional concerns of Western political theory, and tends to be invoked by bilateral aid donors, and OECD, which links good governance to  participatory development and the improvement of women’s rights.

2. Effective governance which is less concerned with the form of government and focuses more on the ability to govern. It is expressed by the World.Bank, which has had to be careful to avoid going beyond its mandate and commenting on its members ‘internal political affairs’

3. Coordination that sees order as the resultant of the actions and interactions of formally constituted governments and other private and voluntary associations. Order is not something imposed by the government’s actors, and cannot be sharply distinguished from them. Three distinct ordering principles or modes of governance can be identified within these relationships: hierarchical rules; market exchanges; and shared values. Any actual policy, program or organisation involves a mix of modes. The governance as coordination approach provides a framework for understanding the role of private sector, non-government organisations, and the state in development .

 

Despite the classification of the definition of good governance, in general good governance has accountability, transparency, openness, and rule of law as its basic components (Bhatta 1998:232). It entails a vast set of democratic processes and institutions at every level of society, from the local council to regional, national and international institutions, that allow the voices of the people to be heard, conflicting interests to be peacefully resolved and a forging of consensus towards greater social progress (Wijkman 1998:2).

 

Good governance aims more than merely efficient management of economic and financial resources, or particular public services to encompass a broad reform strategy to strengthen the institutions of civil society and make government more open, responsive, accountable and democratic. Thus in good governance the efficiency concerns of public management overlap with issue of governance accountability (Minogue et al 1998:6).

 

The universality of the aim of good governance in supporting democracy and human rights raises significant issue of the applicability and the achievement of good governance among diverse countries. International development agencies are criticised of being unaware of structural and cultural differences between developed and developing countries and also within developing countries (Alcantara 1998; Roots 1996). Concept of governance is coined in the North by international development agencies based on Western experiences of development. The OECD document reflects the promotion of the universality of Western model of development while the document lacks of reference of the recent experience of contemporary Asia. The inability to distinguish between regime type and good governance reduces the documents applicability to Asia where good governance thrives amidst political diversity (Roots 1996: 146).

 

The Western concepts differentiate and separate between strong and weak state. Based on Western concepts good governance occurs when the state retrenches, becomes less powerful, assumes a low profile and operates in a network with private interests and groups as a partner scarcely more important than the other (Merrien 1998:58). In the realm of developing countries especially in Asia the division is blurred. In Asia there is a strong but limited government. The success of regimes in East Asia suggest that states are strong when critical and durable limits channel government’s behaviour into acitivities compatible with economic development (Root 1996:141-143). The combination of weak and strong state usually emerges as the successful model of governance in Asia. Hence, the Western notions of good governance is inadequate in explaining the East Asian stories of “failure” and “success” since it has been based on the “flawed neo liberal paradigm” which perceives states as an inefficient actor of development and has thus reduced development to a simple process of technical policy making  (Kielly 1998:1).

 

The African perspective on governance also criticises the universality of good governance (Kruiter 1996). The North imposing their notions of good governance which is coined in the North with emphasis on accountability and transparency is considered as being neglectful and derogatory toward the images of African culture and government since it perceives as though dishonesty (in the form of corruption) among the Africans as the root of development problems in Africa. From the African perspective inefficiency in development process in Africa is more of the problem of incompetencies (capability mobilisation and capacity building) which is inseparable from the past experiences of Western colonialism. Western concept of good governance is also considered as reducing problems of development to merely management issues. It argues that governance is historically contingent, therefore, governance should be separated from the notion of goodness. Good governance should be placed in its historical context. The notion of governance should be based on communal/group with a balance over rights and duties rather than on individual rights. Competency and incentive framework would be the element of good governance together with accountability. The African perspective on governance urge for ‘another governance’ which places equal emphasis on the role of the state and civil society and that is interaction is needed.

 

Another insight puts forward by Alcantara (1998) by criticising the tendency of  international financial institutions in using governance rather than ‘state reform’ and ‘political change’ to avoid severe critics of being undermining the sovereignty of aid recipient countries. The technical rather than social and political consideration has been used in implementing these institutions’ neo-liberal economic programmes more efficiently (Alcantara 1998:107). She continues that this focus on efficiency contributes to the difficulties faced by borrowing countries in implementing specific initiatives. The emphasis on promoting a more efficient government institution and on improving the capability of government creates the standardisation of models of political institution building (Alcantara 1998). World Bank, she notes, has used the concept of good governance on a purely technocratic issue of governing which provides no analysis on the existence of vested interests within and outside the state. Thus it has neglected the political side of development.

 

In between the universal and particular view, Lamour (2000:8-9) argues that good governance is a blend of universal and particular. He specifically explains that although there are similarities of the state: a set of similar looking organisations, legislatures, departments, local governments which carry out a similar set of tasks yet there are also country specificity in implementing governance since the meaning differs among countries. Therefore middle level theories about good governance, between arguments for the universality of good governance and the peculiarity of countries is needed in discussing good governance.

 

These critiques lead us to question the universal applicability of governance and good governance. The governance concept points to the creation of a structure or an order which cannot be externally imposed but is the result of the interaction of a multiciplicity of governing and each other influencing actors (Kooiman & Van Vliet 1993). As the consequence of governance as process determined by actors, who are bound and influenced by their social, political and historical environment, the definition of good governance therefore should be as diverse as to be responsive to different needs and concerns of different societies/groups and should be defined by and for themselves. This concept of good governance should be defined and applied within the specific history and social context of the society in which the concept is being implemented. The concept, strategies and methods of good governance should be based and derived from the local knowledge and experiences and local circumstances. 

Several reasons can be proposed in arguing for the urgency to relate and interpretation of governance and good governance to the diversity of national and local environment among countries. Social values and histories of countries diverse. There are particular conditions in developing countries that may contribute to the inappropriateness in implementing models of governance and good governance which derived from advanced countries. Good definition of good governance must therefore be sensitive to and acknowledges the diversity of nations. The concept of good governance cannot be perceived and implemented as universal ideas with universal application. It must be adjusted to the ‘concrete social settings’ in diverse countries (Alcantara 1998:113)

 

More attention and emphasis need to be given to the political/cultural aspect of good governance such as the strengthening of the capacity of community organisations (civil society) that looks more on the involvement of the society in governing rather than merely focusing on enhancing the technocratic capacity of government as being applied by international development agencies in promoting good governance. He also found that government's performance may depend as much on civic associations, as on institutional design; simple, incremental reform that are consistent with policymakers’ values are easier to transfer; policies adopted by developing countries are vulnerable to reversal at many subsequent points, depending on whether resistance erupts into the public arena, or remains within the bureaucracy (Larmour 2000:12).

 

The above critiques raise significant issues of good governance: universality, ethical issues regarding the sovereignty of countries with their norms, values and historical experiences (qualitative aspect of good governance) and debate on management/technocratic and political aspects of development which needs to be explored in examining the applicability of good governance in developing countries. Does the imposition of good governance not the same with intervening with aid recipient countries’ sovereignty in dealing with their internal affairs? Governance needs embedded values and norms of the people. Concept of governance and good governance as the measurement of governance should be anchored locally based on local knowledge and norms in order to best serve the needs and interests of the people. This critique need to be elaborated on a gender perspective if good governance aim in enhancing popular participation and influence in all aspects of development is to be fulfiled .