DEMOCRATIC  INSTITUTION  BUILDING  IN  RUSSIA’S  REGIONS: GLOBAL  CHALLENGES, DOMESTIC  RESPONSES

 

Andrey S.Makarychev

 

 

Introduction

 

     The interim results of Vladimir Putin’s institutional reforms are very controversial. It is still hard to give clear characterisation of Vladimir Putin‘s  conception of future Russia. This uncertainty is well manifested in Russia‘s regional politics.

         Russian reality has many faces. The challenge to political analysts is to find out which are the crucial elements of the institutional building in Russia, and in which way they are related to wider world-wide developments.

   In this paper I will try to point out the main features of the current processes of democratic institution building in Russia and in its regions and highlight the factors that I think are the driving forces – including outside ones - behind the scene. The question of whether, how and to what extent emerging institutions are influenced by or are to be seen as the result of globalisation forces is very important with regard to Russia’s democratic development.

My two basic arguments might be presented in the following way. First, I think that globalisation has created (though on a rather modest scale) preconditions for maintaining and/or even enhancing political plurality in most of Russian regions. On the one hand, by the end of 1990s it became clear that clan-like sub-national political regimes face serious difficulties in attracting foreign investments and plugging into international cooperative projects. Krasnodar krai, Tula oblast, Primorskii krai, Kirov and Ulianovsk oblasts are good illustrations of politically non-democratic regimes with scarcely developed international relations. On the contrary, as a rule, those regions that work hard on creating economically open market environment and fostering international cooperation, have better results in democratic institution building.

On the other hand, the forces of globalisation have started penetrating into the Russian regions in many direct and indirect ways. One of them is intervention into the regional politis of major Russian financial and industrial groups (FIGs) which might be fairly treated as global actors – both by their potential and geographic scope of operation. They have challenged old regional elites and thus contributed to important transformations of regional regimes towards more transparency and pluralism.

My second argument is that these positive transformations are of rather limited scope, and are unevenly distributed across the huge country. Nevertheless, foreign institutions might take advantage of these changes in the regions as soon as they open better chances for creating business-friendly environment, predictable and corruption-free decision making process, and resourceful non-governmental sector.

 

Pluralism and Globalization: Uneasy Linkage?

 

It is assumed by many Western scholars that “globalisation positively affects democratisation. A higher degree of democratisation opens the political process to a wide array of domestic interest groups”[1]. Yet the projection of this principle onto Russia is not so straightforward. There is a wide spread belief on the part of Russia’s elites and society that, at least for the time being, firm authoritarian rule is needed to stabilize the country. In sociologist Igor’ Kliamkin’s words, “the state is perceived as more important than the democracy”[2].

     In the words of Viktor Kuvaldin, globalisation is conducive to appearance of “mega-society”, which transforms the whole set of social linkages and connections of each individual. The basic and traditional principles of social structuring are being reshaped. The problem is how adequately the political management structures respond to these globally-driven changes. Political institutions – including the regional ones – are perhaps “the weakest chain” of globalisation in Russia[3]. Indeed, it is hardly imaginable to discover the future with the old political norms and instruments.

     Russia’s regional political institutions are in the process of uneasy transformation, which occurs as the cumulative result of both domestic and international developments. The new political norms coexist with the old ones, making their symbiosis an interesting phenomenon to study. In some regions, the inter-elite agreements still derive from the post-Soviet common nomenklatura background, while in more democratic subjects of federation inter-elite settlements are being achieved on the basis of negotiations and the balance of group interests[4].

 

I. Pluralism by Default?

Many Russian scholars are rather pessimistic in their assessments of perspectives for democracy in Russia’s regions. For example, Alexei Chernyshov sticks to the conclusion that there are no roots of democracy in sub-national Russia, and – what is more – provinces are major sources of Russia’s authoritarian tradition and feed up new totalitarian impulses[5]. Closely stays Sviatoslav Kaspe’s assumption about “non-organic” character of Russian federalism, which he thinks turns out to be a myth[6].

In a similar way, Nikolay Petrov argues that the basic explanation of Putin’s reform is that Kremlin is steadily preparing for installing the emergency regime, with increasing percentage of administrators coming from the military and security services[7]. In his logic, regions will easily fall victims of federal centre policies.

     These gloomy views seem to misperceive important aspects of what is going on in the regions. In parallel with re-imposing centralisation in center-periphery relations, the new openings for strengthening institutional democracy appear in the provinces. These new openings might not always be visible, since all of them are of “technical” nature and not necessarily go public[8]. Yet they do exist, which makes their preservation and incorporation into the emerging system of re-centralisation and hierarchisation the highest priority task for Russian democracy[9].

New possibilities are also manifested in increasing the number of political actors within each of the regions and new division of the spheres of their influences. Òhere is much room for pluralism in the regions, and the
federal center seems to tolerate it. It appears that Moscow is positive about giving to the regions some additional powers in politically peripheral matters – for example, the State Pardon Commission was recently dissolved, and its functions were transferred to the regional chief executives. President Putin has positively commented on the chances of some regions to take over some technical functions of the federal agencies and ministries[10]. Basically this tolerance is due to the fact that neither of the regions seems to be able or willing to challenge the federal authority.

Of course, we can’t grasp the meaning of democracy only in terms of pluralism of political actors. This is just one of prerequisites for democracy, and one of criteria to assess the democratic credentials and perspectives of political system. But the more actors perform on the political scene, the more chances are open for transparency to survive and progress.

Electoral statistics also supports the thesis of pluralisation of regional political process. This might be well illustrated by the following table[11]:

 

 

January 2001 – January 2002 elections in the regions (20 gobernatorial campaigns)

Previous 20 regional campaigns (in 2000)

Average number of candidates running for office

7

5

Number of incumbents losing the election

10

7

Number of second rounds held

7

3

Number of winners coming from the  business

5

2

 

This data shows that since 2000 the regional elections became more competitive and demanding. The shoots of pluralism are still there in regions dominated by authoritarian rulers – in Krasnoyarsk krai with its deep split among different elite groups, or Krasnodar krai with a number of politically strong municipal units challenging the supremacy of region’s elite.

As seen from globalisation perspectives, numerical increase of regional political actors is important since the old-style governors might loose their political predominance, which gave them the ability to block a number of projects aimed at tax reform and macroeconomic stabilisation[12], treat the economic enterprises as their fiefdoms, help the insolvent factories to survive without badly needed restructuring, impede financial transparency, and conduct their own customs and export policies[13]. 

1. To start the account for new changes, I would mention that President himself became more involved in regional policy issues – not personally but institutionally. Presidential representatives in the federal districts are new sources of President’s influence in the regions. They have appeared within the framework of Putin’s territorial reform launched in May 2000. This reform has divided the country into seven federal districts. Presidential envoys have essential powers to control the implementation of federal programs in the regions, monitor governors activities, etc. In all districts presidential envoys were quick to become new centres of political power, sometimes alternative to the governors. This made Vitaly Ivanov, the member of the Expert Council of the State Duma’s Committee on Federation Issues and Regional Politics, to assume that Russia is a country of two overlapping federations, competing with each other[14]. This competition makes regional political actors change and apply better strategies.

Presidential representatives try to find new ways of projecting the federal policy onto regions. Among the most widely used methods are PR campaigns, creation of new co-ordinating bodies (like, for example, Association of Municipal Organs and Association of Legislatures in South Federal District), anti-corruption “cleansing” in the regional administrations, etc.  There are many supporters of further strengthening the powers of presidential representatives to institute alternatives to ineffective governors in the regions[15].

These attempts give however mixed results. In 2000 in St.Petersburg and Briansk oblast, for example, Kremlin lost the undeclared contest with incumbent governors Vladimir Yakovlev and Yurii Lodkin[16] respectively. In other cases federal centre policies were more effective. For example, it was the case in
Yakutia where former President Mikhail Nikolaev was unseated, and Viacheslav
Shtyrov (the head of major diamond company "Alrosa") was elected.
Kremlin also has successfully unseated throughout electoral procedures Leonid Gorbenko, the former governor of Kaliningrad oblast, known for ineffectiveness and mismanagement of regional economy. It is quite telling that just a few months afterwards the federal government had issued a seemingly liberal “Concept of Kaliningrad Oblast’s Development” that stipulates transforming this Russian exclave to the export-oriented zone and speeds up the perspectives of its faster co-operation with the EU[17].

       Alexander Kislitsin, the former president of Mari El Republic, known for corruption in his administration, was also defeated with the help of the federal centre. In some cases measures other than electoral were applied – thus, former governor of Kursk oblast Alexander Rutskoi was denied the registration due to procedural misgivings.

In other regions the federal center preferred to stay aloof of the
intra-regional competition, and was ready to work with almost anybody whoever
wins. This was the case of Nizhnii Novgorod oblast where in July 2001 the
election was won by the Communist Gennadii Khodyrev. Yet the point is that
there was no danger to domestic pluralism in the region. Khodyrev has formed
right-centrist government (of technocratic nature, with no Communists), and
appointed his representative in the Federation Council a rather pro-business
figure.

The problem is that Putin is unaware to which direction the presidential representatives ought to move further. Authorities of certain regions are still unwilling to give up their powers acquired under Yeltsin presidency, and obstruct changing their legislation according to federal standards. The Commission on Power Sharing was formed under the aegis of Dmitry Kozak, Deputy Chief of Presidential Administration, but it still lacks clear mission statement and perspective vision. Discussion on the future of seven federal districts are still underway, and the general feeling is that they might give some results only during Putin’s second term in office.

2.     Regional legislatures have consolidated their powers and even managed to receive new rights, which makes them potentially more active and self-assertive players of the regional political scenes. Regional legislatures got the veto power in approving and dismissing the region’s representatives in the upper chamber of the parliament[18]. In some provinces (like Nizhnii Novgorod oblast) the regional legislature has got the right to approve the head of the regional government (though later it was revoked). In Yakutia, Chuvashia, Krasnoyarsk krai, Irkutsk oblast and St.Petersburg legislatures are the strong challengers of the regional executive authorities[19]. A group of Russian scholars came to the conclusion that “fetters that shackle the legislatures in the regions, are less hard than it is the case of the federal parliament"[20]. Again, it works for greater diffusion and dispersion of political power.

As a confirmation of significant political potential of the local parliaments, in June 2001 President Putin has convened a working meeting with the head of legislative assemblies of the most important regions. In the Ural Federal District, the Association of Chairpersons of Regional Legislatures was created, with open support from the presidential representative[21]. The President had made it clear that he would like the regional lawmakers to play more important roles both regionally and nationally (within the framework of the State Council, for example)[22].

At the same time, the whole picture does not seem to be so inspiring. In the regions of Ural, for example, the political role of local legislatures is very much limited, and most of these institutions operate in “structural vacuum” having missed the chance to build up effective partnership with both political and civil society institutions[23].

3.     Political parties are expected to become stronger actors in regional politics. The President has supported the amendments of Igor Egoshin and Boris Nadezhdin aimed at introducing the federal legislation requiring not less that 15% of the local legislators to be elected by party lists, which might eventually diminish political influence of the governors and increase that one of the parties[24]. Alexander Uss, the head of legislature in Krasnoyarsk krai, one of few regions (along with Sverdlovsk and Kaliningrad oblasts) to apply proportional electoral system, suggests that it lays good foundation for political plurality and strengthen local parties[25]. It was telling that some governors (like Ivan Skliarov of Nizhny Novgorod) were quick to reject the idea of giving to the parties greater weight in the regional politics[26] fearing that this will eventually lead to weakening of their patronage over regional politics.

In general, parties might have greater political voice in those regions with sharp political conflicts within governing elites. On the contrary, the more consolidated are the regional political actors, the less chances are for parties to participate in decision making process[27].

One has also to bear in mind however that the new law on parties might give political bonus to the Communists, because they are usually weak at single-winner districts but rather strong as a party with its own political identity and electorate. The right-wing coalition faces the opposite problem: they have sufficient number of attractive personalities but rather weak party support.

4.     In some regions the municipal units became more important than ever before. This is the case of Moscow city where the heads of the city districts were traditionally appointed by Moscow mayor Yurii Luzhkov and gave him much of his power. Now according to the Supreme Court decision they have to be popularly elected, as all heads of municipal units across the country. 125 administrative units would have their own budgets and subsequently become more independent of the all-mighty mayor. This innovation certainly undermines the political monopoly of the mayor Luzhkov[28]. The good news is also that the Supreme Court decision was taken as the reaction to the law suit filed by two local NGO with ostensibly liberal background, which signifies that the dreams about the civil society might become true one day. Yet in other regions like Tatarstan the municipal institutions are still under the direct supervision of the regional authorities.

5.     “Peaceful invasion” of major financial and industrial groups in Russian regional politics is another important matter. These new regional actors systematically buy out the shares of local enterprises and become their owners. For example, “GAZ” car-building factory in Nizhnii Novgorod is under control of “Siberian Aluminium” group led by tycoon Oleg Deripaska. “Krasnoe Sormovo” – major Russian ship-building plant also located in Nizhnii Novgorod - is under control of another politically and economically influential figure Kakha Bendukidze.

          The high-ups of some regional financial and industrial groups have succeeded in achieving direct political goals – thus, Roman Abramovich (owner of “Sibneft’” oil company), Alexander Khloponin (owner of “Norilsk nickel” company) and Boris Zolotariov (top manager of “Yukos” oil company) were elected governors of respectively Chukotka, Taimyr and Evenkia (three Siberian provinces rich of mineral resources). Khazret Sovmen, the wealthiest gold-producer of Russia, in early 2002 was elected the President of small Adygeia.

Hence, the businessmen are still interested in regions, and in some of them they have succeeded in becoming important poles of gravitation.The recent election in Perm’ oblast had brought to power younger and business-oriented group of new leaders. All this might indicate the advent of new type of regional elites, with stronger entrepreneurial culture and much needed management skills[29]. There are strong indications that the federal centre favours the new business-like regional administrators, since it is expected that those business structures that stood behind them would take care of the plethora of regional social issues[30]. It might open new opportunities for foreign investors as well.

     Of course, the impact of FIGs entry into the regional politics differs from one region to another. Republics such as Tatarstan, Bashkortostan, Mordovia, Udmurtia, Yakutia, being inward-oriented semi-autarkies, seem still to keep aloof of external FIGs influence. In relatively small subjects of federation heavily dependent on a single enterprise, the most typical pattern could be described as “oligarchic monopolism”. The term coined by Rostislav Turovsky from the Centre for Political Technologies means that there is a dominating economic actor eager to convert its financial and managerial potential into a political one (the case of Taimyr). In larger regions the governors have to consider different strategies for different economic actors. This is what could be called “oligarchic pluralism”, a more complicated model of relations between political rulers and economic agents based on balance of interests and search for compromises (examples are Khanty-Mansy Autonomous okrug, Sverdlovsk, Yaroslavl’, Tomsk, Murmansk oblasts). In case if the regional political structures are insufficiently inclusive and adaptive, the region faces the perspective of “oligarchic wars”, with each of competing economic groupings trying to undermine the rivals[31].

     In terms of political pluralism, it is important that the governors  face the challenges from major Russian financial and industrial groups operating in their regions. As seen from globalisation perspective, the situation seems to be more complicated.

On the one hand, some of FIGs are in favour of implementing more protectionist measures in order to defend their businesses from international competition. Among FIGs owners and top managers strong are anti-WTO feelings. Yet on the other hand, major FIGs are both domestic and global actors, since they trade their shares in international securities market, look for expanding strategic partnership with foreign companies, and hire international lawyers for defending their rights in the courts abroad. It makes the governors get adjusted to the new environment which is a part of the global market development.

6.     The federal government had ruled that some business practices – traditionally supervised by the regional nomenklatura – have to be altered. The most telling example is the requirement of the Russian government  to distribute quotas for fish exportation not by governors’ decisions – as it used to be - but through open auctions. The Minister for Economic Development and Commerce German Gref has said that the auction is the purest and the most transparent mechanism for distributing the quotas[32]. Needless to say that all governors of maritime regions were fiercely against this decision, being fully aware that it would eventually destroy their paternalistic networks and bring new actors (including foreign ones) to their domains[33].

7.     In some regions media actors are becoming more politically active than before. Thus, “Mediasoyuz” group with well developed regional network is intended to become an alternative to the Russian Union of Journalists on the local level. “Mediasoyuz” patronized by Kremlin is conducting a number of regional campaigns for “honest election” and greater political transparency.

         Thus, as we have seen, in a number of regions the new polycentric model of power is being installing (according to Natalia Lapina’s study, Perm’ oblast is one of the most illustrative cases[34]). The “old guard” in these regions is gradually losing their exceptionality, which is a good sign[35]. They are slowly becoming one of several actors, which pushes them into strong competition with other power brokers. Regional elections were in 2001-2002 even more competitive and intensive, the fact that might be a good prove of democratic perspectives in the regions[36]. In the light of the ostensible rise of influence of liberal economists, these developments might be rather fruitful. Market economic policies[37] would definitely necessitate more diversification within regions and more operational freedom for each of them.

      Yet I am not sure that this new constellation of political forces in the regions should be however treated as a direct result of Putin’s political design. Rather this is “pluralism by default”, one of unintended outcomes of Putin’s policies. In this sense we consent with the Russian political analyst Alexei Kara-Murza who has said that paradoxically ‘liberalism is the by-product of strengthening the statehood’[38].

       Doubtless, one should not overestimate the significance of this “pluralism by default”. The problem is that “both the elite in Moscow as well as in the regions have almost no experience in creating a federalist state from below and not from the top. They largely do not see and understand the regionalisation/decentralisation as a chance to build up a real and viable federalist/confederalist state from below. Furthermore, they overlook the globalisation trends in economic-political affairs which are strengthening those processes, regardless of what Russia is doing”[39].

       President is still in search for those social actors – apart from the governmental bureaucracy – that could take greater responsibility for country’s recovery and modernisation[40]. It might be rather likely that the real effect of new regional political polycentrism will be weaker than it could have been expected. Yet the new developments have created some opportunities for new wave of democratic institution building in the regions. Assuming that the political strength of civil society might be measured – among other factors - by the number of political alternatives available, we see some positive developments in the recent time[41].

 

II. The Dark Side of Putin’s Regional Policy

     Now, let us turn to major setbacks of Putin’s regional reforms as seen from the perspectives on country’s modernisation.

1.     New representatives of the regions in the upper chamber of the parliament look neither convincing nor effective. Previously the governors and the chairpersons of regional legislators obtained their membership in the Council of Federation ex officio, in their capacity of office holders. Putin’s reform reversed this practice. Senators now have to be nominated by the governors and by the regional legislatures. The separation of senatorship from the governorship theoretically makes possible the appearance of new political leaders at the grass roots level.

     But this only a part of the story. The new members of the upper chamber lack strong political reputation and appropriate background and are not even sufficiently known among the regional political elites. For example, Saratov oblast Duma has delegated to the upper chamber of the federal parliament Valentin Zavadnikov who is the deputy chairman of “EES Rossii”, the major energy supplier all across the country[42]. Viktor Glukhikh, former director of “Gosoboronprom” (major arms exporting agency), was approved as representative of Yaroslavl’ oblast in the Council of Federation[43].

      This new practice of appointing influential – but having little relevance to the regional politics - figures to the Council of Federation questions the whole concept of popular representation in the upper chamber of the parliament. The fear is that the new nominees will be very much dependent upon the political will of either governors or mighty economic institutions, and the upper chamber will look like “mobile phones” institution, with no clear political coherence, identity and mission. All this already gave start to talks about “political uselessness” of the upper chamber as such, its possible fusion with the State Council, and other options. In terms of enhancing political pluralism in the regions, is that vitally important to make the Federation Council members popularly elected, since it will further diversify regional political landscapes.

2.     The President failed to find proper procedural tools for constitutionally removing those governors that are ineffective, corruptive or break the laws. For example, Evgeny Nazdratenko, the former governor of Far Eastern Primorskii krai known for numerous scandals and inefficiency, had resigned only in exchange for decent job in Moscow. This was a habitual sample of political bargaining “under the carpet” instead of fully transparent institutional procedures. What is also telling is that it is still unclear whether there is a strategy of integration of Primorskii krai to the Asian Pacific trans-boundary co-operation models after Nazdratenko’s demise.

3.     Putin was unable (or unwilling) to block the introduction of the legal norm allowing the incumbent governors to run for re-election for the third consecutive term. Putin’s inaction was an overt concession to the most influential governors led by Tatarstan President Mintimir Shaimiev. Needless to say that the third-term amendment would only strengthen clan-like political systems in certain regions.

4.     The judiciary in the regions – as well as countrywide - still waits for being reformed. The courts system lacks genuine independence from the political authorities, is weak, corrupted and scarcely funded. Russia still has not complied with the international standards in human rights, criminal prosecution, and law enforcement[44]. This is evidently one of major barriers for international business co-operation.

5.     Fighting with excessive (and often unconstitutional) powers of the governors, Putin deprives the regions of their resources. This is basically done for political purposes. For example, the tax distribution ratio under Putin became much more favourable to the federal centre, at the expense of the regional budgets. In international arena, regions were deprived the right to borrow abroad. These developments could easily fit into the logic of the Ministry of Foreign Affairs approach according to which “federation components can score the greatest success on the international scene only with support from the federal organs of the state”[45]. Yet the thing is that the regional elites will undoubtedly try to compensate their losses through imposing more control over local businesses and self-government bodies, which would complicate democratic institution building at grass-roots level.

6.     There is still too much obsession with secrecy and security regulations in the regions. The Western media has covered a number of cases. In Omsk the regional office of Federal Security Service (FSB) announced that it had reprimanded an American lecturer Elizabeth Sweet after counter-intelligence learned she had asked students to examine the economic health of local businesses. In Kaluga Russian military analyst Igor’ Sutyagin is on trial for high treason, accused of passing state secrets. In Krasnoyarsk, a University scientist was charged with high treason for fulfilling a contract with a Chinese company to supply research on shielding satellites from radiation. In Vladivostok, a military court restarted trial against Grigorii Pasko, a military journalist accused of treason after helping Japanese TV report on the Russian Fleet’s dumping of nuclear waste at sea[46].

 

 

Economic Openness and Institutional Democracy: Are There Strong Linkages?

 

The institutional basis for regional democracy in Russia is still weak: thus, according to the study of influential Council for Foreign and Defence Policies, gubernatorial elections of 1996-98 have led to lesser governability of the regions, both economically and politically[47]. Yet most interesting is that the Russian case demonstrates that global integration does not necessarily need to lead to an enhancement of internal democratisation processes. Let us take basic economic criteria reflecting the region’s openness and inclusion to international economic and financial networks and see whether the most advanced regions were those with higher democratic standards.

-                            Banking infrastructure development. Here we have Moscow city as its indisputable leader, followed by St.Petersburg. Others in this list are regions with authoritarian governments - Bashkortostan, Tatarstan, and Krasnodar krai. Bashkortostan also is the second-largest region (after Moscow city) in terms of number of local banks’ branches spread all across Russia[48].

-                             “Big privatisation” rating (privatisation of large federal property). The leaders – as by mid-1990s – are the regions with traditionally conservative political background: Riazan’, Belgorod, Volgograd, Oriol oblasts, Stavropol’ krai, Buriatia (privatisation scale is above 80%). By the same token, regions with rather pluralistic political regimes (what Vladimir Gel’man calls “community of elites” or “struggle by the rules” models, with competition of different actors and compromise strategies widely employed[49]) such as Samara and Perm’ oblasts are located at the bottom of this list, with 30-50% of privatisation scale.

-                            “Small privatisation” rating. Here we find among the leaders (more than 97% of small- and medium size enterprises being privatized) Moscow city, St.Petersburg and Saratov oblast, along with Republic of Altai, Khakassia, Dagestan and Riazan’ oblast (the last four regions generally match Gel’man’s “winner takes all” model of political regime, with high levels of political monopoly and scarcely developed competitive strategies).

-                            Establishing free economic zones. The majority of the regions with FEZs are politically conservative, widely relying on administrative resources and political patronage (Primorskii krai, Kaliningrad oblast, Altai krai, Ingushetia, Kalmykia).

-                            Foreign investments per capita. In this category the leaders – apart from Moscow city – are Magadan oblast, Jewish and Yamalo-Nenets Autonomous okrugs, Sakhalin, Arkhangelsk Oblast, Tatarstan, Komi Republic, Omsk and Tomsk oblasts. Only the last two regions’ regimes could be called moderately pro-democratic (“community of elites”, in Gel’man’s terminology), all others are predominantly monocentric and  traditionalist. It is telling that, in Vladimir Klimanov’s assessment, foreign investors’ interest is basically focused on those regions with lower social standards and weaker financial institutions[50], and consequently which weakly developed political resources which tend to be insufficient for democratic institution building.

-                            Financial-industrial groups formation. By the end of 1990s about one half of them were registered in Moscow, while the rest were located in Voronezh and Riazan’ oblasts (the two most notorious samples of “Red Belt” regions), St.Petersburg, Nizhnii Novgorod, Vladivostok, Yekaterinburg, and Tula.

-                            Participation in more than one inter-regional associations of economic cooperation. This criterion might prove the region’s search for more diversified economic strategies and new resources. Yet politically speaking, the regions of this category are far from democratic standards (Kaliningrad, Briansk, Smolensk, Tula, Chita oblasts, Buriatia, Aginsky Autonomous okrug), with just a few exceptions like Novgorod oblast usually considered as one of most democratically advanced in Russia.

-                            Securities market development. In fact, this is one of few economic indicators that could be neatly associated with the characteristics of political regime. The first inter-regional centers of securities market operations emerged in 1992-93 – St.Petersburg, Novosibirsk and Ekaterinburg (the main city of Sverdlovsk oblast) – shared clearly visible pluralist and institutionally democratic political background.  Some other centers to appear by 1997 – including Nizhnii Novgorod and Samara (along with Vladivostok and Rostov-on-Don) – had also significant potential for competitive politics.

-                            Establishment of recruiting agencies based on international standards. Again, starting from the end of 1980s Moscow and St.Petersburg took the lead, yet by mid-1990 the new centers of recruitment have appeared – Ykaterinburg, Novosibirsk, Nizhnii Novgorod, Samara, Saratov. Later on, Perm’ and Omsk joined the list of the most advanced regions in this field. All these regions have rather credible – according to Russian standards - democratic background. Yet at the same time, we may find among those regions with more or less developed labour market practices Krasnodar krai, Voronezh, Lipetsk, Yaroslavl’ oblasts that have much less democratic credentials[51].

-                            Inter-regional trade barriers. This is another valuable indicator that could give us an adequate idea of region’s political profile. All the regions that have imposed administrative impediments for production outflow were ruled by illiberal elites with weak or non-existent sense of modernisation and international integration like Mari El Republic, Udmurtia, Krasnodar, Stavropol’ and Khabarovsk krais, Briansk, Vologda, Ivanovo and Yaroslavl’ oblasts.     

     What we see from this analysis is that if we take a single criteria of economic openness and try to find out what is its influence in the sphere of democratic institution building, in most cases the positive correlation is not evident, to say the least. In most localities the regional rent-seeking actors are motivated by getting material profit from globalisation, without inciting democratic institution building. Autocratic personalistic regimes could be more advanced in terms of plugging into the trans-national economic and financial networks than those adhered to separation of powers and democratic procedures.

      Yet if we choose more complex criteria, the linkage between economic openness and democratic institutionalisation will become more traceable.

-                            The aggregate indicator (proposed by Alexander Parkansky) encompassing the region’s export and import volumes and dependence on world market demand. The five top regions are Kemerovo, Samara, Cheliabinsk, Perm’ Oblasts, and Krasnoyarsk krai[52]. Some of them (perhaps Samara and Perm’ oblasts) are more advanced than others in terms of democratic institutions building, yet one can’t find in this group neither overtly repressive or isolationist regimes.

-                            The same goes for the comprehensive and perspective (till 2003) assessment of regions’ economic development done by the Ministry of Economic Development and Trade. This index contains a greater variety of indicators (gross regional product, the volumes of investments and foreign trade, financial sustainability, share of employees in small and medium businesses, etc.). Moscow, as it should have been expected, is on the top of the group of most advanced regions, followed by Samara oblast, Yamalo-Nenets Autonomous okrug, Murmansk oblast, Komi Republic, St.Petersburg, Tomsk oblast, Sakhalin and Khabarovsk krais. This group is very uneven in terms of its members’ political regimes, but most of them roughly correspond to what Gel’man called “community of elites” (elite consensus) or “war by the rules”.  Not less telling is that the regions that were placed at the very bottom of the list are either politically fragmented (Kabardino-Balkaria, Karachaevo-Cherkessia, Dagestan, Ingushetia), corrupted (Mari El), or monocentric (Buriatia, Tyva)[53].

-                            What is called by Mikhail Alexseev the “magnet regions” accounting for 50% of Russia’s foreign trade and 70% of direct foreign investments (all having diversified economy, strong science and technology base, developed access infrastructure and urban milieu) is a group of regions with predominantly pluralist and competitive political regimes (Nizhnii Novgorod, Samara, Sverdlovsk and Leningrad oblasts) with few exceptions of Tatarstan and Moscow city[54].

-                            Leonid Vardomsky’s index of regions’ economic openness is also useful for the purpose of our analysis. He singles out three groups of economically open regions (“central”, “maritime and borderland”, and “export-driven” groups), with 29 regions included. Only a limited number of them might not qualify for democratic standards (again, these exceptions are Moscow city, Tatarstan, Bashkortostan, Krasnodar krai, Vologda and Lipetsk oblasts, etc.)[55].

The information given above makes the whole picture extremely paradoxical. Yet the more criteria we apply, the more evidently we see that economic globalisation is a significant factor shaping the behavior of regional elites.

Also important is that the greatest variety of factors of democratic institution building has to be taken into account. Plurality of regional political actors and competitiveness of regional policy making is only one of them. Another important factor is voting preferences of the regional constituencies. If we take it into consideration, the “deviant” cases (Moscow city, Tatarstan and other regions with undeniable potential for economic globalisation but weakly developed or non-existent democratic procedures) might be perceived differently. The point is that, according to Nikolay Petrov and Alexey Tishkov’s typology of regional electoral behaviour, such regions with weak democratic credentials as Moscow city, Ingushetia, Karelia, Yaroslavl’ oblast, Yamalo-Nenets Autonomous okrug, and Komi ought to be located in the right (pro-market) wing of political spectrum since their voters overwhelmingly support non-communist and non-nationalist parties thus demonstrating their commitment to reforms and modernisation[56].

In fact, globalisation erects “constrained corridor” for regional policy makers in a sense that it drives the regional regimes (with different speed and in different ways) to stick to those norms and procedures that are dominant on a global scale.

 

 

 From “Cold Globalization” to “Warm” One[57]

 

We have to keep in mind that external forces (basically political ones) can sometimes have negative effects on democratic institution building. For many Russians, the term “globalisation” has a negative connotation and is understood as a sort of global “US imperialism” against which Russia has to defend herself. At the subnational level, we can notice also negative impact in agrarian or border regions (mainly in the southern and far eastern parts of Russia), which are more than other regions exposed to foreign influences such as illegal migration, drug trafficking or cross-border smuggling. It is no coincidence when we find authoritarian and nationalistic regimes in these crisis-racked areas of Russia.

      At the beginning of the 21st century it became clear that the whole concept of relations between Russia and the West is in crisis and has to be seriously reconsidered. This crisis is very observable in the lack of new and fresh ideas concerning the role of non-central actors in Russia-West communication. It is very much telling that the 2000 Russia-focused report of the Carnegie Endowment “The Program of Renewal” has not a single mention of the US policies with regard to the Russia’s regions[58].

       Seemingly, this is both a political and intellectual problem. The American policy expert community seems to loose the sense of direction of the Russian transition and is overwhelmingly disoriented by the lack of clear indications of progress in the field of regional institution building. Missing or uncertain correlation between the economic openness and the state of the regional democracy is also discouraging for those who in the beginning of 1990s propagated the theory of quick institutional changes within Russia. Also controversial are political profiles of the regional leaders, the bulk of whom could not be classified as either democrats or communists. All these are perceptual difficulties, but having clear political implications.      

       The truth is that the West has had already the same kind of disappointments and frustration in tackling other non-Western nations. As William Easterly, the senior adviser of the World Bank’s research group puts it, much of the efforts to assist the developed countries have failed to attain the desired results. “Sub-Saharan Africa has not emerged from a decades-long economic crisis, Asia remains the home of the majority of the world’s poor, Latin America has known only erratic and low growth, the Middle East has not converted oil riches into sustained development”, he argues[59].

      Turning globalisation into the force that sustains democracy-building in the regions of Russia has to be implemented by switching from “cold globalisation” paradigm (expert-driven, basically technical, and touching mainly financial, managerial and macroeconomic matters) to a “warm one” – based on deeper involvement of social institutions, more sensitive to societal and humanitarian needs, and focused on grass-roots exchanges among non-professionals. It is wrong to anticipate that issuing academic recommendations, giving “conditional loans” to Russia, and focusing exclusively on industrial modernisation will bring the country closer to the global world.

       It seems that the basic challenge for the Western assistance to Russia is reshaping priorities to foster concentration of resources[60]. Strangely enough, still there were no comprehensive measurement of the successes and failures of Western assistance programs, some of which were very costly. We think it is time to apply adequate assessment tools to find out in which regions and in which areas the international community did achieve positive institutional changes, and in which it failed.  

 

Conclusion

 

      Global challenges have exercised some – though rather modest and fragmented – impact over Putin’s reforms. One of its most essential incentives was to make Russia more competitive internationally through redistribution and rationalisation of resources and rearranging political relations. In this sense Putin’s policies are responding to the global challenges. Yet basically all those changes are of domestic background, which makes them even more durable and sustainable phenomena than those imposed from abroad.

        Foreign actors however might take advantages of the new developments in the regions. They could benefit from diversification of political resources and appearance of new set of autonomous power contenders in the regions. Under the new circumstances there is much more space for political bargaining and coalition building for the sake of investment promotion, business development and all kind of international projects. There is also more room for fighting the corruption in the regions, which is one of basic impediments for greater international participation: the more actors operate within the region, the more checks and balances unfold, and the more transparent the decision making process might become[61].

     But these are only chances. The nearest future is to show whether the new opportunities will be duly implemented both internationally and domestically.  The reform would fail in the long run unless there is clear indication that it stimulates better business conditions, strengthens middle class, fosters openness and transparency, and eradicates corruption - all what is much needed for smooth and effective international cooperation.

 

 

 

 

 

 



[1] Roy Suter, Marc Holitscher, ‘The Impact of Globalization Processes on the Cohesion of the Modern State: The Cases of Quebec and Scotland’. Paper presented to the ECPR Joint Sessions, University of Warwick, 23-28 March 1998. P.5.

[2]Liberal Mission’ Foundation (Moscow) Web site, [http://www.liberal.ru/sitan.asp?Num=1]

[3] Nezavisimaya gazeta Web site, [http://scenario.ng.ru/printed/interview/2000-10-11/5_future.html]

[4] Anais Marin, ‘Paradiplomatic Activities of the Russian Federation’s Provinces in the Transition Period and Their Influence on Federal Foreign Policy Making. A Case Study of St.Petersburg as an Actor of the Regionalisation Process within the Baltic Sea Region’. Research Paper. European University of St.Petersburg, February 2001, p.39.

[5] Alexei Chernysov, ‘Region kak subiekt politiki’ (Region as a subject of politics). Saratov University Press, 1999, pp.85, 139, 147.

[6] S.I.Kaspe, ‘Konstruirovat federatsiu: Renovatio Imperii kak metod sotsialnoi inzhenerii” (Constructing the federation: Renovatio Imperii as a social ingineering method), in Prostranstvo vlasti: istoricheskii opyt Rossii i vyzovy sovremennosti (Power Space: Historical experience of Russia and contemporary challenges). Moscow: Moscow Public Science Foundation, 2001, p. 32-33.

[7] Petrov’s statement at the conference on “Russia’s Regions in International Security Environment”, Zurich, 6 July, 2001.

[8]Political Comments’ Web site, [http://www.politcom.ru/p_pr.html]

[9]Liberal Mission’ Foundation Web site, [http://www.liberal.ru/sitan.asp?Num=55]

[10] Profil’, 21 January 2002, p.62.

[11] Dmitry Oreshkin, ‘Novie Russkie strakhi’ (New Russian Fears), Moskovskie novosti, N 5, 5-11 February, 2002, p.5.

[12] Transformatsia. William Davidson Institute and World Bank, May-July 2000, p.15.

[13] Transformatsia. William Davidson Institute and World Bank, June 1999, pp.23-24.

[14]National News Service’ Web site, [http://www.nns.ru/Elect-99/analit/comments/kom1695.html]

[15] Dmitrii Badovskii, ‘Sistema federal’nykh okrugov i institut polnomochnykh predstavitelei Presidenta’ (The system of federal districts and the institution of Presidential plenipotentiary representatives), in  Federalism v Rossii (Federalism in Russia). Kazan’: Institute of History and Institute of Federalism, 2001, p. 73.

[16] Regiony Rossii. Information and analytical bulletin of Inter-regional foundation for Presidential programmes. N 1 (21), 15 January 2001, p.13.

[17] Expert magazine Web site, [http://www.expert.ru/server/current/bigput.shtml]

[18]  Elections in Russia’ Web site, [http://www.vybory.ru/journal/journ7/j7arta2.html]

[19] Nikita Ivanov, ‘Nachinaetsia noviy etap reformy federativnogo ustroistva Rossii’ (On the eve of the new stage of Russia’s federal reform), http://www.businesspress.ru/newspaper/article.asp?mId=40&aId=72594]

[20] A.S.Avtonomov, A.A.Zakharov, E.M.Orlova, ‘Regional’nie parlamenty v sovremennoi Rossii’ (Regional parliaments in today’s Russia). Moscow Public Science Foundation, Working Papers N 118. Moscow, 2000, p.11.

[21]Strana’ Information Agency Web site, [http://ural.strana.ru/print/992437224.html]

[22]Strana’ Information Agency Web site, [http://www.strana.ru/print/992959217.html]

[23] A.D.Kirillov, B.A.Kirillov, ‘Zakonodateli Urala’ (Law-makers from the Urals). Yekaterinburg: Ural’skii rabochii, 2000, p.104.

[24]Strana’ Information Agency Web site, [http://www.strana.ru/print/992948447.html]

[25]Strana’ Information Agency Web site, [http://www.strana.ru/print/992882102.html]

[26] Interview with Ivan Skliarov, 26 June, 2001, [http://www.strana.ru/print/993631922.html]

[27] Valerii Solovei, “Politicheskie partii v publichnoi sfere rossiiskikh regionov: sotsial’nii aspekt” (Political parties in the public sphere of Russian regions: social aspect), in  Federalism i publichnaia sfera v Rossii i Kanade (Federalism and Public Sphere in Russia and Canada). Moscow: Gorbachov Foundation, 2001, p. 92.

[28]Strana’ Information Agency Web site, [http://www.strana.ru/print/985974522.html]

[29] http://www.gazeta.ru/2001/04/12/zolotarev.shtml

[30] http://www.ancentr.ru/komment/2001/04/343-12.shtml

[31] Rostislav Turovsky, ‘Gubernatory i olygarkhi: istoria vzaimootnoshenii’ (Governors and oligarchs: history of relationship), [http://www.politcom.ru/c_b.html]

[32] Vremia novostei, N 29, 19 February, 2001.

[33] Vasily Spiridonov, ‘Poslednie dary moria’ (The Last Gifts of the Sea), Itogi 13 March (2001), pp. 32-37.

[34] Natalia Lapina, ‘Modeli vlasti v regionakh i problemy razvitia regional’noi ekonomiki’ (The patterns of power in the regions and the problems of regional economic development), in ‘Rossia v usloviakh transformatsii’ (Russia in Transformation). Foundation for Political Centrism Development, Seminar Proceedings N 3. Moscow: 2000, pp. 51-70.

[35] For example, the governors were forbidden to apply different electoral tricks like sudden resignation and arranging new election on a short notice in order to marginalize their opponents (gerrymandering).

[36] Nezavisimaya gazeta Web site, [http://scenario.ng/printed/expertize/2001-03-14/2_strong.html]

[37] Nezavisimaya gazeta Web site, [http://regions.ng.ru/printed/far/2000-10-31/1_egor.html]

[38] Liberal Mission Foundation, [http://www.liberal.ru/sitan.asp?Num=2]

[39] Frank Umbach, ‘Russia as a „Virtual Great Power“: Implications for its Declining Role in European and Eurasian Security’, European Security, Vol.9, No.3 (Autumn 2000), p.94.

[40] Alexei Zudin, ‘Grazhdanskoe obshestvo ili sovetskaya obshestvennost’(Civil society or Soviet-style public), [http://www.politcom.ru/arhiv/p_vz24.html]

[41] Rurik Ahlberg, ‘Economic Development, Civil Society and Democratic Orientation: a Study of the Russian Regions’, Journal of Communist Studies & Transition Politics. Vol.16, N 3 (September 2000), pp. 21-38.

[42] Kommersant, 13 September 2001, p.2.

[43] Kommersant, 15 October 2001, p.3.

[44] Andre Gerrits, Ger van den Berg, ‘Human Rights and Legal Change in the Russian Federation’, Helsinki Monitor. Quarterly on Security and Cooperation in Europe. Vol. 11 (2000). No.3, pp. 6-22.

[45] Valeriy Orlov, ‘Foreign Policy and Russia’s Regions’, International Affairs. A Russian Journal of World Politics, Diplomacy and International Relations. Vol.46, No.6 (2000), p.83.

[46] Michael Wines, ‘With Shiver of Fear, Russian Sense a Return to Policy-State Ways’, International Herald Tribune, June 15 (2001), pp.1,5.

[47] ‘Problemy i perspektivy razvitia federalizma v Rossii’ (Problems and Perspectives of the Federalism Development in Russia),  [http://www.svop.ru/doklad7.htm]

[48] V.V. Klimanov, ‘Regional’noe razvitie i ekonomicheskaya samostoiatel’nost’ subiektov Rossiiskoi Federatsii’ (Regional development and economic autonomy of the subjects of Russian Federation). (Moscow: Editorial URSS 2000), pp. 116-165.

[49] Vladimir Gel’man, ‘Transformatsia i rezhimy. Neopredelionnost’ i eyo posledstvia’ (Transformation and regimes. Uncertainty and its effects), in ‘Rossia regionov: transformatsia politicheskikh rezhimov’ (Russia of regions: transformation of political regimes). Edited by V.Gel’man, S.Ryzhenkov, M.Brie. (Moscow: Ves’ Mir, 2000), p.55.

[50] Klimanov V.V. Op.cit. P.156.

[51] Alexey Bordin, ‘Rynok truda v sovremennoy Rossii: istoria i geografia’ (Labour market in today’s Russia: history and geography). Novoe pokolenie, N 4, vol.2. Moscow: summer 1998.

[52] ‘Ekonomicheskoe razvitie Rossii i mirovie tendentsii na rubezhe vekov’ (Russia’s economic development and world economic trends at the edge of the centuries). (Moscow: ISKRAN, 1996), p.238.

[53] Russia’s Investment Opportunities Web site,  [http://www.ivr.ru/regions/index.php?a=view&title=298]

[54] Mikhail Alexseev, ‘Russia’s Periphery in the Global Arena: Do Regions Matter in the Kremlin’s Foreign Policy’. Program on New Approaches to Russian Security. Policy Memo Series. Memo N 156 (October 2000).

[55] ‘Rossia perekhodnogo perioda: global’nie i regional’nie problemy ekonomiki’ (Russia in transition: global and regional economic problems). (Moscow: Epikon, 2001), pp.126-128.

[56] Nikolay Petrov, and Alexei Tishkov, ‘Vybory-99 v regional’nom izmerenii’ (Elections of 1999 in regional dimension), in “Regiony Rossii v 1999” (Russia’s Regions in 1999). Yearly addendum to “Russia’s Political Almanac”. Edited by Nikolay Petrov (Moscow: Gendal’f, 2001), p. 209.

[57] The title of this chapter was borrowed from my colleague Professor Andrey Dakhin who coined it at his presentation at the international congress of Twin Cities in Nizhny Novgorod, June 14, 2001.

[58] ‘Programma obnovlenia’ (The Program of Renewal). Report of the Russian-Eurasian program of the Carnegie Endowment for International Peace (Moscow: 2000)

[59] William Easterly, ‘The failure of development’, Financial Times, 4 July 2001, p.13.

[60] Andrey Kortunov. ‘Kak pomoch vuzam Rossii vstat’ na obe nogi’ (How to Help Russian Universities to Stand on Two Feet), [http://www.e-edu.ru].

[61] ‘The Russia Initiative: Reports of the Four Task Forces’. Carnegie Corporation of New York, 2001, pp.112-113.