Project Description
How electoral systems affect democratic accountability in Russian
regions
Research Proposal
Introduction
The choice of electoral system inescapably has a significant impact on the
nature of regional government and policy decisions it makes. The locus of
the current study is exploring the electoral system - accountability nexus.
There is no need to stress the importance of this issue that has become the
focus of ongoing and hot debate in both the public sphere and academic circles.
In the Russian context this issue is even more important since corruption
was not just redistributing goods in ways detrimental for both the manifest
purposes and prescribed procedures of governance, but created major distortions
in the democratic process as well.
Accountability is a broad concept that encompass several aspects - monitoring,
auditing, oversight, control and punishment (Schelder, 1999). Governments
must be subject to oversight from below. In the scholarly literature this
control mechanism is conceptualized as vertical accountability - strengthening
the ties between the regional government and its constituents by increasing
its transparency and empowering capacity of citizens to influence policy decisions.
Citizens must be able to oversee and restrain the political process in regional
governments in virtually each stage of the policy decision-making and implementation
processes, assess the outcome of the policy decisions and if needed, impose
sanctions on the accountable party. In order to advance this form of accountability
a strong network of binds connecting the government to general public has
to be established. Seemingly, this strategy is more feasible in increasing
both answerability and enforcement dimensions of accountability in
nascent democracies. It can be done by developing endogenous remedies for
abuses, one of which is via development of various agents of accountability
that ensure persuasiveness of formal institutions in decision-making process
and lead to greater commitment of politicians to democratic norms and procedures.
The comparison on the regional level, as chosen for the presented project,
allows for a ceteris paribus situations: the influence of a single variable
(electoral system) is testable and the regularities for theory building are
easily testifiable. Moreover, by limiting the analysis to the sub-national
units we hold several intervening variables constant: historical background,
cultural differences, federal political institutions, and so forth. In the
chart below the general scheme of the behavioral outcomes of institutional
change is presented, where the highlighted sections represent the causal chain
in question: ‘electoral system – accountable behavior of politicians’.
Electoral systems, as institutions in general, determine ‘relevant’ actors
and their preferences, their allowed actions, the information given to the
actor, and the particular procedures used to produce the outcome: the behavior
of the actors.
1. Theoretical background
Is there a link between the electoral system and the level of political
accountability? Dominant political theories point out that the plurality
rule is more inductive for vertical accountability (Powell, 1982, Blais and
Dion, 1990, Persson, Tabellini and Trebbi, 2001), since plurality system
tends to produce one-party majority government. This type of government,
in turn, provides political stability, strong leadership and decisive elections,
which allow greater accountability (Blais, 1991).
However, under conditions of extreme party underdevelopment, the opposite
outcome can be the case. As it was demonstrated by Moser (1999), in constraining
the number of parties and providing political stability, the proportional
representation may be more successful than the plurality system. The fragmented
character and low institutionalization of the Russian party system provide
grounds for the hypothesis that runs counter to the conventional wisdom mentioned
above: proportional representation can be more inductive for accountability.
Another explanation draw on the assumption that electoral rules vary in
their monitoring capacity and therefore create stronger or weaker constraints
on elected officials (Rose-Ackerman, 2001). It is assumed that in candidate-centered
systems, contrary to party-centered systems, politicians are more directly
accountable to voters, consequently, the plurality rule makes elections better
monitoring device to hold politicians accountable. Under the plurality system,
candidates are elected by geographical constituency, which makes them accountable
to a distinct constituency, while in proportional representation system individual
politicians are first accountable to the party.
We do not know whether the greater accountability, associated with plurality
system is causal, or it is due to a third factor causally linked to both country’s
government’s accountability and to its selecting plurality system. In order
to circumvent this problem, it is advisable to choose the cases, where the
influence of these factors can be easily controlled for. One of the possible
ways to do so is shifting from cross-country to cross-regional (within one
country) empirical research.
2. Research Design
Comparative analysis tradition, which goes back to Aristotle, lies in the
heart of political science. Using comparative methods, a research can acquire
features of quasi-experimental analysis, introducing controllable conditions
analogous to those in the natural sciences. Comparisons using methodology
that places a particular unit of analysis (country, province, municipality)
in a wider prospective can lead to research outcomes that are valid beyond
the borders of that unit. Along with cross-country comparisons, the comparisons
focused on sub-national units, such as states, provinces, or even municipalities
have become academically recognized area of comparative political research.
One of the most recognized advantages of this form of comparison is the
relatively large number of units available for comparisons: unlike countries,
regions/municipalities are more numerous, which allows for more sophisticated
statistical analysis. For example it is possible to control for socio-structural
(size, occupational structure), and cultural differences. Second, the danger
of spurious correlation is much lower than in the case of cross-country comparisons
due to greater homogeneity of regions within a country than of countries
themselves. This makes it easier to isolate explanatory variables from confounding
factors on the regional level than on national level. Third, the comparability
of the available data in terms of measures is much easier to attain between
the regions of one country than between different countries.
The analysis of Russian regions comply the two key requirements for comparative
studies: they provide variety in dependent and independent variables, and
the N has an impressive value – 89 regions. Even though federal government
suggested that the regional elections were conducted under first-past-the-post
system in single-member districts, in a bulk of regions this suggestion was
ignored. Starting from the first regional elections 1994-1995, mixed, or ‘two-vote’
system for parliamentary election systems was adopted in eight regions (in
Krasnoyarsky krai, Sverdlovskaya, Saratovskaya, Kaliningradskaya oblasts,
Ust’-Ordynsky Buryanskii and Koryakskii AOs, and republics of Tyva
and Marii-El), six regions added run-off systems (City of St Petersburg, republics
of Buryatia, Chuvashia, North Ossetia, Sakha and Tatarstan), and many other
regions employed multi-member districts (McFaul and Nikolai Petrov, 1998).
Russian regions not only differ in the choice of electoral systems, but
they are relatively autonomous. The turnout in regional elections is not
significantly lower than in national elections (Slider, 1996), this fact
indicates the importance of the regional elections to voters. Second, the
autonomy of the regions implies the wider scope of political institutional
choices available for regional politicians. Therefore it is feasible to identify
the mechanisms that drive regional politicians to boost ‘classic’ mechanisms
of accountability and/or facilitate the emergence of non-elective independent
specialized bodies of oversight. The project will identify how electoral
rules create powerful institutional limitations on the propensity for corruption.
Therefore, in the case of Russian regions, the variety of regional electoral
systems along with uniformity of majority of political institutions allows
for an accurate analysis of the impact of the electoral systems on political
developments . The project will take form of ‘large-N’ statistical research,
which is complemented by a case study. Units of comparison are regional governments
in Russia. The research seeks to understand which type of electoral system
is more likely to enhance political accountability of representatives to the
people. In order to fulfil the mentioned tasks the research is designed to
investigate:
1. Assessment of the actual levels of accountability in the regional governments
2. Interrelationships between the electoral rule and actual levels of accountability
3. Case studies will provide insights into the specific mechanisms, which
connect the electoral systems to creation of institutions that boost or hinder
accountability.
2.1. Selection of units of analysis
In the first part of the research, all 89 regions of Russia will be analyzed.
The design of the second part of the research, case study, requires that the
selected cases are based on categories of explanatory variables, and research
involves finding out the values of dependent variables for each region. Consequently,
regional governments that vary with respect to their electoral system will
be selected for the second part of the project.
2.2 Analysis of actual accountability
This part of project will involve the assessment of the actual level of
accountability in both ex ante and ex post forms, in other words, it will
be analyzed whether and how officials are prevented from taking decisions
which are illegal, arbitrary or impolitic, and to what extent unlawful or
improper action, already implemented, is sanctioned. Therefore, I do not
restrict the study to injurious actions previously taken but also take into
account measures that are designed to oversee actions that are not
yet implemented, and in some cases not even enacted.
2.3. The relationship between electoral system and actual accountability
of regional governments.
In this part of the research I will explore the nexus between the electoral
rule and the level of accountability of sub-national governments in Russia.
In-depth interviews will reveal the ways in which different electoral systems
bring different mechanisms of vertical accountability.
3. Policy Implications and Dissemination of the Results
The policy proposals will expose ways to increase the effectiveness of the
mechanisms of vertical accountability, which can take the form of changes
in practice or even proposals for electoral reform. The outcome of this research
will provide valuable information for better informed policy choices.
I intend to disseminate the results of the proposed project in several ways,
as follows
1. the results will be presented in forthcoming conferences and workshops
related to the topic.
2. final outcome will be published in Russian language as an article in
Russian academic journal
3. the outcome of the research will be also disseminated via several (in
Russian and English language) Internet outlets
4. the outcome will be published as a brochure in Russian in order to disseminate
the results among general public and particularly, targeted audience of regional
legislators and their aides.
References
- Blais, A. (1991). The Debate over Electoral Systems. International
Political Science Review, vol.12, No.3, 329-260
- Blais, A. and S. Dion, (1990). Electoral systems and the consolidation
of new democracies.” In: Democratic Transition and Consolidation in Southern
Europe, Latin America and Southern Asia, (D. Ethier, ed.) London: Macmillan.
- Colton, Timothy J. (1990). The Politics of Democratization: The Moscow
Election of 1990. Soviet Economy, vol.6, N4, P.285-344.
- McFaul, M., and N. Petrov, (1998) Political Almanac of Russia, 1989-1997
(Washington, DC, Carnegie Endowment for International Peace,. Pp.600-601.
- Moser, R.G. (1999) Electoral Systems and the Number of Parties in
Postcommunist States. World Politics .Vol. 51: 359-84.
- Powell, G. B. Jr., (1982). Contemporary Democracies: Participation,
Stability and Violence. Cambridge MA.:Harvard University Press.
- Persson, T., G. Tabellini, and F. Trebbi, (2001) “Electoral Rules
and Corruption.” Mimeo ftp://ftp.igier.uni-bocconi.it/homepages/tabellini/tp001213.pdf
- Przeworski, A. and H. Teune, (1970). The Logic of Comparative Social
Inquiry. New York : Wiley Interscience, 1970, 31
- Schedler and L. Diamond (eds.) (1999) The Self-Restraining State :
Power and Accountability in New Democracies. Boulder, Colo. : L. Rienner,
21
- Rose-Ackerman, S. (1999). Corruption and Government: Causes, Consequences
and Reform. New York: Cambridge University Press.
- Slider, D. (1996) Elections to Russia’s Regional Assemblies’ Post-Soviet
Affairs 12, 3,
- Solnick, S. (1998). Gubernatorial Elections in Russia, 1996-1997.
Post-Soviet Affairs, vol. 14, N1, p.48-80
Back to my Home Page